SlideShare a Scribd company logo
1 of 88
Introduction to
competition law
Julija Jerneva
Application of EU Competition law
•EU consists of 27 Member States
•EU and three other countries are part of European
Economic Area (EEA)
EU competition law applies to all countries in the EEA
Institutions
EU Institutions:
•European Commission
– enforces competition policy through directorate general (DG)
– Can launch surprise investigations at company premises
– Can require large mergers to be approved
•EU Member States have their own competition laws and authorities
•Companies must comply with competition laws of EU and Member
States
What is competition law?
• Competition law exists to protect the process of competition
in a free market economy
– A system where the allocation of resources is determined solely
by supply and demand in free markets
• Competition wanted because of the market result it
produces
– Efficiency
– Low prices
– Innovations
• Competition rules limits the freedom of the market players to
protect the process of competition
Economic efficiency
- main objective of competition policy
• Competition gives the best utilisation of scarce
resources
– Perfect competition v monopoly
• Perfect competition
– Pareto optimal use of resources
» None could be made better of without someone being made
worse of
» Consumer welfare maximized
– Productive efficiency
» Constant pressure on costs
» Cost reductions is the only means whereby firms can stay in
business and increase profits
• Monopoly
– Leads to an inefficient allocation of resources
» Quantity supplied less the quantity which would be supplied in a
competitive market
• Perfect competition, monopoly and competition in
the real world
– Workable competition
”workable competition”
• The ECJs concept of ”workable competition” related
to what competitin is inteded to achieve in the
Community context
– Not one of the concepts of ”workable competition” found
in economic theory
» But influenced by the theory
• Concept of competition in the Merger Regulation
compared:
– Prohibits concentrations creating or strengthening a
dominant position ”as a result of which effective
competition would be significantly impeded in the
common market”
How to pursue the goals?
• Prevent agreements restrictive of competition
– Horisontal agreements (Among competitors)
– Vertical agreements (between parties at different levels
of the production or distribution chain)
• Control market power and its abuse
• Control oligopolistic markets
• Prevent mergers which lead to a concentration in
market power
Overview of EU Competition Law
Aspects of primary importance to business:
•Article 101 TFEU makes illegal any agreement or
concerted practice between undertakings that
significantly restricts competition within EEA
•Article 102 TFEU makes it illegal for dominant company
to abuse its dominant position in market
•Mergers
EU competition law deals with anti-competitive agreements between
companies and unilateral conduct of individual companies with
dominant position
Article 101 TFEU: Purpose and Rationale
Article 101 prohibits agreements that disrupt free-market
principles and hinder competitiveness
Article 101 promotes independent decision-making over -
•Pricing
•Whether to sell in one country or several
Decisions should be based on desire to attract new customers and retain
existing ones
Agreements that restrict two or more companies’ commercial options are
likely to violate Article 101
Article 101(1) TFEU
• The following shall be prohibited as incompatible with the
internal market: all agreements between undertakings,
decisions by associations of undertakings and concerted
practices which may affect trade between Member States and
which have as their object or effect the prevention, restriction or
distortion of competition within the internal market, and in
particular those which:
Article 101(1) TFEU
(a) directly or indirectly fix purchase or selling prices or any other
trading conditions;
(b) limit or control production, markets, technical development, or
investment;
(c) share markets or sources of supply;
(d) apply dissimilar conditions to equivalent transactions with other
trading parties, thereby placing them at a competitive disadvantage;
(e) make the conclusion of contracts subject to acceptance by the
other parties of supplementary obligations which, by their nature or
according to commercial usage, have no connection with the subject
of such contracts.
Article 101(2) TFEU
2. Any agreements or decisions prohibited pursuant to this Article
shall be automatically void.
Article 102 EC: Abuse of Market Dominance
Article 102 is a companion of Article 101
•Directed at unilateral conduct of companies
dominant in their market
•Targets abuse of dominant position
Abuse of a dominant position: Anti-competitive business practice
undertaken to maintain or increase market position
•Includes unfair pricing, restriction of production output, and imposing
discriminatory terms on trading partners
Violations of Article 102 can result in serious fines and other penalties
Article 102 TFEU
• Any abuse by one or more undertakings of a dominant position
within the internal market or in a substantial part of it shall be
prohibited as incompatible with the internal market in so far as it
may affect trade between Member States.
Article 102 TFEU
• Such abuse may, in particular, consist in:
(a) directly or indirectly imposing unfair purchase or selling prices
or other unfair trading conditions;
(b) limiting production, markets or technical development to the
prejudice of consumers;
Article 102 TFEU
(c) applying dissimilar conditions to equivalent transactions with
other trading parties, thereby placing them at a competitive
disadvantage;
(d) making the conclusion of contracts subject to acceptance by
the other parties of supplementary obligations which, by their
nature or according to commercial usage, have no connection
with the subject of such contracts.
Consequences of Non-Compliance
Non-compliance has serious consequences:
•Fines up to 10% of annual worldwide turnover
•Liability in damages under national law
•Voiding of contract
•Criminal liability
•Substantial expenditure of time and money
•Bad publicity
•Investigations by other competition authorities
The sources of EC competition law
• The Treaty Articles
• Regulations
– Merger regulation
– Block exemptions
• Judgements
– European Court of Justice
– Court of First Instance
• Commission notices and guidelines
• Commission decisions
• Annual reports from the Commission
• Other documents
Some basic concepts
• Market power
• Market definition
• Barriers to entry
• S-C-P paradigm
The concept of market power
• Competition law concerned first and foremost with
the problems that occur when a firm or two or more
firms possess market power
• A firm or firms that possess market power can enjoy
some of the benefits available to the true monopolist
– Market power presents undertakings with the possibility
of limiting output and raising price, which are clearly
harmful to consumer welfare
Market Power
• Market Power is the ability of a firm or a group of firms in a
market to profitably raise prices, reduce quality, or slow down
innovation for a significant period of time compared to these
outcomes in a competitive market
Analysis of Market Power
• Market structure approach / Indirect approach
• Market definition
• Market shares
• Market concentration
• Barriers to entry and expansion
• Perception of market participants
• Competitive effects analysis / Direct approach
• Predict post-merger price effects
• Elasticity of demand
Relevant market definition
Commission Notice on the definition of relevant market for
the purposes of Community competition law (also available in
Latvian!)
Relevant product market
 'A relevant product market comprises all those products and/or
services which are regarded as interchangeable or substitutable
by the consumer, by reason of the products' characteristics, their
prices and their intended use`
Relevant geographic market
 'The relevant geographic market comprises the area in which the
undertakings concerned are involved in the supply and demand
of products or services, in which the conditions of competition
are sufficiently homogeneous and which can be distinguished
from neighbouring areas because the conditions of competition
are appreciably different in those area`
Basic principles for market definition
 Competitive constraints:
 demand substitutability
 supply substitutability
 potential competition
Demand substitution
 starting from the type of products that the undertakings
involved sell and the area in which they sell them,
 additional products and areas will be included in, or excluded
from, the market definition
 depending on whether competition from these other products and areas
affect or restrain sufficiently the pricing of the parties' products in the
short term
SSNIP test
 small but significant and non-transitory increase in price (SSNIP)
 hypothetical monopolist or cartel could profit from a price
increase of 5% for at least one year (assuming that "the terms of
sale of all other products are constant)?
Demand substitution
 Will the customers switch to readily available substitutes or to
suppliers located elsewhere in response to a hypothetical small
(in the range 5 % to 10 %) but permanent relative price increase
in the products and areas ?
Cellophane Fallacy
 It may happen that using the SSNIP test one defines the relevant
market too broadly, including products which are not substitutes
 Du Pont (a cellophane producer) argued that cellophane was not
a separate relevant market since it competed with flexible
packaging materials such as aluminum foil, wax paper and
polyethylene
Critical loss
 Where demand elasticities cannot be estimated
 Defined as the maximum sales loss that could be sustained as a
result of the price increase without making the price increase
unprofitable.
 Where the likely loss of sales to the hypothetical monopolist (cartel) is
less than the Critical Loss, then a 5% price increase would be profitable
and the market is defined
Demand substitution example
 Soft-drinks with flavour A vs those with flavour B?
 Price = 10 (12 after the increase)
 Sales = 1000 units (800 after the increase)
 Variable costs:
 remaining at the same level
 Increase
 Decrease
 If the increase in price produces too much consumer substitution which
is not compensated by the increase in price nor the reduction in costs?
 The "market" formed by this only product is not "worth monopolising" as
an increase in prices would not be profitable
Supply substitution
 suppliers are able to switch production to the relevant products
and market them in the short term without incurring significant
additional costs or risks in response to small and permanent
changes in relative prices
 Example: paper
Potential competition
 conditions of entry
 Low barriers - potential competition will represent an effective
competitive constraint
 High barriers - potential competition is not likely to represent an
effective competitive constraint
Evidence – product dimension
 Evidence of substitution in the recent past
 Views of customers and competitors
 Consumer preferences
 Barriers and costs associated with switching demand to potential
substitutes
Evidence – geographic dimension
 Past evidence of diversion of orders to other areas
 Basic demand characteristics
 Views of customers and competitors
 Current geographic pattern of purchases
 Trade flows/pattern of shipments
 Barriers and switching costs associated to divert orders to
companies located in other areas
Barriers to entry
• Barriers to entry hinders the emergence of potential
competition which would otherwise constrain the
incumbent undertaking
• Crucial when determining market power
– May have high market shares but no market power if
there are no barriers to entry
Analysing barriers to entry
• Market definition and entry by production substitutes
• Market conditions and historical entry
• Assessment of absolute cost advantages
• Assessment of strategic (first mover) advantages
• Vertical foreclosure and exclusion
• Predatory behaviour
• Assessment of entry impediments
S-C-P approach
• Structure (competitive, monopolistic, monopolistically
competitive, or oligopolistic)
• - number of competitors, buyers, suppliers
• - level of product standartisation
• - barriers to entry
• - scale economies, costs structures
• Conduct (output decisions and pricing behavior, merger
policies, R&D, investment & advertising policies)
• Performance of the industry (production efficiency and
profitability)
Article 101(1) – the elements
• The meaning of “undertaking”
• Forms of co-operation caught
– The meaning of agreement
– Decisions by associations of undertakings
– Concerted practices
• “Object or effect the prevention, restriction or
distortion of competition”
• Effect on trade between member states
• De minimis
The concept of an “undertaking”
• Article 101 (and 102) applies only to “undertakings”
– Undertaking not defined in the EC Treaty
• ECJs definition of an undertaking:
– “the concept of an undertaking encompasses every entity
engaged in an economic activity regardless of the legal status of
the entity and the way in which it is financed”
» Case 41/90, Höfner and Elsner v Macrotron, para 21
• “Every entity”
– The legal form of the entity irrelevant
» All kind of companies
» Persons
• Self employed
• Not employees (Opinion of GA Jacobs, case C-67/96, Albany)
» Associations
• “Associations of undertakings” directly caught
• But can also be found to act as “undertakings”
• Example: Co-operatives, P&I clubs
• Exception: trade unions representing their members
– The entity’s engagement in “economic activity” decisive
• “Economic activity”
– Any activity consisting in offering goods and services on
a given market
» Wide definition
State bodies
• Exercising official authority
– ECJ: Article 101 does not apply to agreements concluded by bodies
“acting in their capacity as public authorities and undertakings
entrusted with the provision of a public service” (case 30/87,
Bodson)
– Includes tasks which are typical those of a public authority
– Such tasks are not of an economic nature
– Can to a certain extent be financed through fees of economic
contributions
• Engaging in economic activity
– Will be regarded as an “undertaking”
– How the public body is organised is not decisive
Some statistics
Ten Highest Cartel Fines Per Case Since
1969
Year Case name Amount in €
2008 Car Glass 1 383 896 000
2009 Gas 1 106 000 000
2007 Elevators and Escalators 992 312 200
2010 Airfreight 799 445 000
2001 Vitamins 790 515 000
2007 Gas Insulated Switchgear 750 712 500
2008 Candle Waxes 676 011 400
2010 LCD 648 925 000
2010 Bathroom fittings 622 250 782
2006 Butadiene Rubber/Emulsion Styrene Butadiene
Rubber
519 050 000
Ten Highest Cartel Fines Per Company
Since 1969
Year Case name Amount in €
2008 Saint Gobain (Car glass) 896.000.000
2009 E.ON (Gas) 553.000.000
2009 GDF Suez (Gas) 553.000.000
2001 F. Hoffmann-La Roche AG (Vitamins) 462.000.000
2007 Siemens AG (Gas insulated switchgear) 396.562.500
2008 Pilkington (Car glass) 370.000.000
2010 Ideal Standard (Bathroom fittings) 326.091.196
2007 ThyssenKrupp (Elevators and escalators) 319.779.900
2008 Sasol Ltd (Candle waxes) 318.200.000
2010 Air France / KLM (Airfreight) 310.080.000
Overview of Article 101 TFEU
§1 – The Prohibition
Rule (+ examples)
Are prohibited as incompatible with the internal market:
“all agreements between undertakings, decisions by
associations of undertakings and concerted practices which
may affect trade between Member States and which have as
their object or effect the prevention, restriction or distortion of
competition within the internal market (…)”
§2 – The Rule of
Nullity
“Any agreements or decisions prohibited pursuant to this
Article shall be automatically null and void”
§3 – The Exception
Rule
§1 may be declared inapplicable to agreements which:
1. “contribute to improving the production or distribution of
goods or to promoting technical or economic progress,
2. allow consumers a fair share of the resulting benefit,
and which do not:
1. impose on the undertakings concerned restrictions which
are not indispensable;
2. afford such undertakings the possibility of eliminating
competition”
Basic structure of analysis of Art.101
• Agreements violating Article 101(1)
• and not capable of being exempted under Article 101(3)
• are null and void (Article 101(2))
Agreement:
horizontal or vertical
Step one
• Agreement?
• Between undertakings?
• Appreciable effect on trade?
• Object or effect?
Step two
• Derogations (Article 101 (3) TFEU)
• Rule of reason (incl. block
exemptions)
Elements (step one)
1. “Agreements”
2. Between “undertakings”
3. Which have appreciable effect on intra-state trade
4. Which have as their object or effect the prevention,
restriction or distortion of competition
Unilateral practices/behaviour
• Unilateral action NOT prohibited under Article 101
• Unilateral action is subject to rules of competition law only
under Article 102 (abuse of dominance)
Mergers
• Are “worse” than agreements”
• Joint ventures between the companies (depending on the level of
integration):
• Analysed under the merger rules; or
• Analysed under the Article 101 rules
Mergers Agreements
Eliminate competition Reduce competition (preserve at
least some level of competition)
Leave permanent effect on the
market
Leave temporary effects on the
market
Agreements
The concept of an “agreement”
• ”Agreement”  widely construed
– It is sufficient if the undertakings in question should have expressed
their joint intention to conduct themselves on the market in a specific
way
» Alignment of the competition parameters available to them
• “joint intention”  a legally binding agreement not necessary
– The form of no importance (oral, signed, unsigned)
– “gentlemen’s agreements”
– The agreement does not have to be exhaustive
» It is enough just to set the broad framework for the undertakings market conduct
• The engagement of the parties in the agreement
– It is enough to be partly engaged in the collaboration
» Breach of contract regarding parts of the agreement
– Passive “members”
– An excuse if an undertaking has been “forced” into a cartel?
• Collaboration through the establishment of a company (joint
ventures)
“Decisions of undertakings”
• Collusion can take place through the medium of an
association: Directly covered by art 101(1)
– Makes it possible to hold associations directly liable
• Association
 widely defined
• Decision
 every statement made with the object or effect of influencing the
commercial behaviour of the association’s members
– Does not have to be binding (e g recommendations)
“Concerted practices”
• A form of co-ordination where undertakings, without
concluding any sort of agreement or establishing a plan of
action, knowingly substitute practical co-operation between
them for the risks of competition
– This criteria avoids that situations where companies collaborate without
any kind of agreement but only on the basis of a common understand
falls outside article 101(1)
• It is contrary to the rules on competition for a producer to
co-operate with his competitors, in any way whatsoever, in
order to determine a co-operated way of action or to ensure
its success by prior elimination of all uncertainty as to each
others conduct regarding the essential elements of that
action
– ECJ, case 48/69, ICI v Commission
Proving concerted practices
• Direct or indirect contact
• Meeting of minds or some kind of consensus
– Exchange of information
– Unilateral disclosure
– Public announcements
• Subsequent behaviour in the market
• Indirect evidence of intention?
Can a concerted practice be inferred from
circumstantial evidence alone?
• A question of the use of economic evidence in
competition cases
• Parallel market behaviour alone in itself not a
concerted practice
• BUT: It may however amount to strong evidence of
such a practice if it leads to conditions of competition
which do not correspond to the normal conditions of
the market having regard to the nature of the products,
the size and numbers of undertakings, and the volume
of the said market power
– ECJ, case 48/69, ICI v Commission
• Oligopoly markets and economic evidence
– Joint dominance
The distinction between “agreement” and
“concerted practices”
• Overlapping concepts
• No precise distinction
– And no use for a precise distinction
• “Concerted practice” important mainly where the
Commission or the Courts is forced to rely upon
circumstantial evidence alone
Undertakings (market participants)
Competition law and math
Single economic unit doctrine
• Two or more separate legal undertakings can be treated as on
undertaking
– if the undertakings “form an economic unit within which the subsidiary
has no real freedom to determine its course of action on the market,
and if the agreements or practices are concerned merely with the
internal allocation of tasks as between the undertakings”
» Case 30/87, Corinne Bodson
• Agreements between two undertakings within a single
economic unit not regarded as an agreement “between”
undertakings
– Escapes the prohibition in article 101(1)
• The rationale:
– No freedom to take decisions regarding the market
conduct
» Regarded as unilateral conduct
» May be caught by article 102 if the undertaking has a dominant
market position
– Internal allocation of functions
• The other side of the coin:
– If a subsidiary engages in anti competitive agreements
the mother company will also be regarded as part of the
agreement
• The test of control
– If a parent company owns more than 50% of the shares
in a subsidiary interdependency is presumed
– Minority share holdings may also give control if combined
with specific rights attached to them
– One large shareholder and many small
– Joint control (50/50)
» Jointly controlled companies must belong to a single group of
companies to be regarded as part of one economic unit
The parent company’s responsibility for
infringements committed by subsidiary
• Case C-97/08 Akzo Nobel NV vs. Commission
”[W]here a parent company has a 100% shareholding in a subsidiary
which has infringed the Community competition rules (…) there is a
rebuttable presumption that the parent company does in fact exercise a
decisive influence over the conduct of its subsidiary (…) The Commission
will be able to regard the parent company as jointly and severally liable for
the payment of the fine imposed on its subsidiary”
100% (or close to) of shares in subsidiary gives rise to presumption
Parent company must show that the subsidiary acted independently on
market – difficult (impossible?)!
Maximum fine increases – 10% of group turnover
If parent company has been involved in prior cartel – increase in fine
Increased risk of being subject to specific increase for deterrence
Cross-border trade effect
Cross-border trade effect
• EU competition rules apply to practices which affect trade
between Member States
• Impact «within the internal market» («effects» doctrine)
• EU-based firms reach an anticompetitive agreement over
price/quantities on US markets – EU competition law is not applicable
• Non-EU based firms reach an anticompetitive agreement over
price/quantities on EU markets – EU competition law is applicable
Cross-border trade effect
1. Must be appreciable
2. Means decrease, increase or simply diversion of trade
Appreciable effect
• The stronger the market position of the undertakings concerned,
the more likely it is that an agreement or practice capable of
affecting trade between Member States can be held to do so
appreciably
• BPB Industries and British Gypsum, Case T-65/89
• BUT: appreciability requirement was also fulfilled when the sales of
the undertakings concerned accounted for about 5 % of the market
• Miller, Case 19/77
“Object” or “Effect”
• “The distinction between „infringements by object‟ and
„infringements by effect‟ arises from the fact that certain forms
of collusion between undertakings can be regarded, by their
very nature, as being injurious to the proper functioning of
normal competition”
• Competition Authority v BIDS and Barry Brothers, Case C-209/07
Object cases
• The object-category consist of “obvious restrictions of
competition”
• European Night Services v Commission, Joined cases T-374-375/94,
384/94
• The “object” rule can be described as a presumption rule:
• if object is found, harmful effects on competition are presumed
• certain types of agreements under normal market conditions always, or
almost always, restrict competition
Object cases
• Horizontal agreements:
• fixing prices
• sharing markets
• limiting outputs
• Vertical agreements
• Fixed and minimum resale price maintenance
• Absolute territorial protection
• Restrictions on passive sales
• Other cases, listed in the “block exemptions”
Effects cases
• All cases, not falling within the “object box”
• Negative effects on competition within the relevant market are
likely to occur when:
• the parties individually or jointly have or obtain some degree of market
power and
• the agreement contributes to the creation, maintenance or
strengthening of that market power or allows the parties to exploit such
market power.
Economics and competition
Economic theory usage
• How can the agreement hinder competition?
• Is collusion likely to occur on a given market?
• Is cooperation between competitors likely to succeed or fail?
Will it be easy or difficult?
The prisoners’ dilemma
Prisoner A
Prisoner B
Remain silent Confess
Remain silent 0, 0 25, 15
Confess 15, 25 20, 20
Firm A
Firm B
Collude Cheat
Collude 20, 20 15, 22
Cheat 22, 15 17, 17
The prisoners’ dilemma
• Prerequisites for a successful cartel and what complicates the
cartel?
• The problem of cheating?
• Efficiency, savings from the horizontal cooperation
What complicates collusion?
• Demand side
• Elastic demand (can the cartel set higher prices?)
• Balancing buyer power?
• Differentiated (vs homogenous products)
• Demand booms as a characteristics of the market)
• Non-stable demand
What complicates collusion?
• Supply side
• Low seller concentration
• Existence of competitors with elastic supply
• Ease of entry
• Cost assymmetries between cartel members
• Prior collusion history on the market (more attention from competition
authorities)
Need for the possibility of high gains
• Elastic and constant demand
• Potential fines? (active/inactive competition authorities)
• Members want and can cheat without being detected
Organisation
• Need to meet, agree
• Need to communicate regularly
• Many competitors vs “few” competitors
• Reinhard Selton, the Nobel prize winner in “Four are few and six are
many”:
• Profitable to collude if less than 5 cartel members
• More attractive to cheat if more than 5 cartel members
Thank you!
• Julija Jerneva
• Mobile: +371 29131597

More Related Content

What's hot

6. price squeezes with positive margins in eu competition law. economic and ...
6.  price squeezes with positive margins in eu competition law. economic and ...6.  price squeezes with positive margins in eu competition law. economic and ...
6. price squeezes with positive margins in eu competition law. economic and ...Matias González Muñoz
 
Competition law-review 5 mar2010 eng julija-debora.c
Competition law-review 5 mar2010 eng julija-debora.cCompetition law-review 5 mar2010 eng julija-debora.c
Competition law-review 5 mar2010 eng julija-debora.cJulija Jerneva
 
Predicting Business Cartels Sharma
Predicting Business Cartels  SharmaPredicting Business Cartels  Sharma
Predicting Business Cartels Sharmammsharmacg
 
Business law in Practice
 Business law in Practice Business law in Practice
Business law in PracticeMaruf Bappy
 
Google - European Union - Rule of Law - Legitimate Business Justification - M...
Google - European Union - Rule of Law - Legitimate Business Justification - M...Google - European Union - Rule of Law - Legitimate Business Justification - M...
Google - European Union - Rule of Law - Legitimate Business Justification - M...Clifton M. Hasegawa & Associates, LLC
 
Monopoly report
Monopoly reportMonopoly report
Monopoly reportjaymin1696
 
An overview of competition law in Malaysia
An overview of competition law in MalaysiaAn overview of competition law in Malaysia
An overview of competition law in MalaysiaAdeline Chin YF
 
The relationship between intellectual property rights and competition law
The relationship between intellectual property rights and competition lawThe relationship between intellectual property rights and competition law
The relationship between intellectual property rights and competition lawDiganth Raj Sehgal
 
Dominant Position :Competition Law(Competition Act,2002)
Dominant Position :Competition Law(Competition Act,2002)Dominant Position :Competition Law(Competition Act,2002)
Dominant Position :Competition Law(Competition Act,2002)Bibhu Manik
 
EU Competition.horizontal agreements
EU Competition.horizontal agreementsEU Competition.horizontal agreements
EU Competition.horizontal agreementsJulija Jerneva
 

What's hot (20)

CMA and UK Cartels
CMA and UK CartelsCMA and UK Cartels
CMA and UK Cartels
 
6. price squeezes with positive margins in eu competition law. economic and ...
6.  price squeezes with positive margins in eu competition law. economic and ...6.  price squeezes with positive margins in eu competition law. economic and ...
6. price squeezes with positive margins in eu competition law. economic and ...
 
Competition law-review 5 mar2010 eng julija-debora.c
Competition law-review 5 mar2010 eng julija-debora.cCompetition law-review 5 mar2010 eng julija-debora.c
Competition law-review 5 mar2010 eng julija-debora.c
 
Economic analysis and evidence in abuse cases – Break-out Session 3 – Techniq...
Economic analysis and evidence in abuse cases – Break-out Session 3 – Techniq...Economic analysis and evidence in abuse cases – Break-out Session 3 – Techniq...
Economic analysis and evidence in abuse cases – Break-out Session 3 – Techniq...
 
Competition provisions in trade agreements – MÜLLER – December 2019 OECD disc...
Competition provisions in trade agreements – MÜLLER – December 2019 OECD disc...Competition provisions in trade agreements – MÜLLER – December 2019 OECD disc...
Competition provisions in trade agreements – MÜLLER – December 2019 OECD disc...
 
Predicting Business Cartels Sharma
Predicting Business Cartels  SharmaPredicting Business Cartels  Sharma
Predicting Business Cartels Sharma
 
EU LAW OG PDF
EU LAW OG PDFEU LAW OG PDF
EU LAW OG PDF
 
NILS Summer Law School Kochi - April 2015
NILS Summer Law School Kochi -  April 2015NILS Summer Law School Kochi -  April 2015
NILS Summer Law School Kochi - April 2015
 
Business law in Practice
 Business law in Practice Business law in Practice
Business law in Practice
 
Small and developing competition agencies – Competition Commission South Afri...
Small and developing competition agencies – Competition Commission South Afri...Small and developing competition agencies – Competition Commission South Afri...
Small and developing competition agencies – Competition Commission South Afri...
 
Google - European Union - Rule of Law - Legitimate Business Justification - M...
Google - European Union - Rule of Law - Legitimate Business Justification - M...Google - European Union - Rule of Law - Legitimate Business Justification - M...
Google - European Union - Rule of Law - Legitimate Business Justification - M...
 
Monopoly report
Monopoly reportMonopoly report
Monopoly report
 
An overview of competition law in Malaysia
An overview of competition law in MalaysiaAn overview of competition law in Malaysia
An overview of competition law in Malaysia
 
The relationship between intellectual property rights and competition law
The relationship between intellectual property rights and competition lawThe relationship between intellectual property rights and competition law
The relationship between intellectual property rights and competition law
 
Dominant Position :Competition Law(Competition Act,2002)
Dominant Position :Competition Law(Competition Act,2002)Dominant Position :Competition Law(Competition Act,2002)
Dominant Position :Competition Law(Competition Act,2002)
 
Monopoly
MonopolyMonopoly
Monopoly
 
How can competition contribute to fairer societies? – AKMAN – November 2018 O...
How can competition contribute to fairer societies? – AKMAN – November 2018 O...How can competition contribute to fairer societies? – AKMAN – November 2018 O...
How can competition contribute to fairer societies? – AKMAN – November 2018 O...
 
Small and developing competition agencies – Competition Commission of Malaysi...
Small and developing competition agencies – Competition Commission of Malaysi...Small and developing competition agencies – Competition Commission of Malaysi...
Small and developing competition agencies – Competition Commission of Malaysi...
 
EU Competition.horizontal agreements
EU Competition.horizontal agreementsEU Competition.horizontal agreements
EU Competition.horizontal agreements
 
Monopoly
MonopolyMonopoly
Monopoly
 

Similar to Competition.introduction.final

The need to have an effective Competition Law regime
The need to have an effective Competition Law regimeThe need to have an effective Competition Law regime
The need to have an effective Competition Law regimeAjithaa Edirimane
 
Competition.introduction(part2)
Competition.introduction(part2)Competition.introduction(part2)
Competition.introduction(part2)Julija Jerneva
 
Competitionact2002 090902133438-phpapp01
Competitionact2002 090902133438-phpapp01Competitionact2002 090902133438-phpapp01
Competitionact2002 090902133438-phpapp01Mudit Sharma
 
Competitionact2002 090902133438-phpapp01
Competitionact2002 090902133438-phpapp01Competitionact2002 090902133438-phpapp01
Competitionact2002 090902133438-phpapp01Sushant Verma
 
Compt. act
Compt. actCompt. act
Compt. actdomsr
 
Mrtp to competition when the world at large is a single platform for trade an...
Mrtp to competition when the world at large is a single platform for trade an...Mrtp to competition when the world at large is a single platform for trade an...
Mrtp to competition when the world at large is a single platform for trade an...92_neil
 
Competition act 2002
Competition act 2002 Competition act 2002
Competition act 2002 Vijay Mehta
 
Competition Act, 2002
Competition Act, 2002Competition Act, 2002
Competition Act, 2002paramalways
 
Competition Assessment: The OECD Toolkit
Competition Assessment: The OECD ToolkitCompetition Assessment: The OECD Toolkit
Competition Assessment: The OECD ToolkitOECD Governance
 
competition act 2002
competition act 2002competition act 2002
competition act 2002Manish Tiwari
 

Similar to Competition.introduction.final (20)

The need to have an effective Competition Law regime
The need to have an effective Competition Law regimeThe need to have an effective Competition Law regime
The need to have an effective Competition Law regime
 
Competition.introduction(part2)
Competition.introduction(part2)Competition.introduction(part2)
Competition.introduction(part2)
 
Competitionact2002 090902133438-phpapp01
Competitionact2002 090902133438-phpapp01Competitionact2002 090902133438-phpapp01
Competitionact2002 090902133438-phpapp01
 
Article 102 TFEU
Article 102 TFEUArticle 102 TFEU
Article 102 TFEU
 
Competitionact2002 090902133438-phpapp01
Competitionact2002 090902133438-phpapp01Competitionact2002 090902133438-phpapp01
Competitionact2002 090902133438-phpapp01
 
Compt. act
Compt. actCompt. act
Compt. act
 
CCI15.9.2011
CCI15.9.2011CCI15.9.2011
CCI15.9.2011
 
Mrtp to competition when the world at large is a single platform for trade an...
Mrtp to competition when the world at large is a single platform for trade an...Mrtp to competition when the world at large is a single platform for trade an...
Mrtp to competition when the world at large is a single platform for trade an...
 
Competition act 2002
Competition act 2002 Competition act 2002
Competition act 2002
 
Price discrimination – Damien GERADIN – Edge Legal Thinking – November 2016 O...
Price discrimination – Damien GERADIN – Edge Legal Thinking – November 2016 O...Price discrimination – Damien GERADIN – Edge Legal Thinking – November 2016 O...
Price discrimination – Damien GERADIN – Edge Legal Thinking – November 2016 O...
 
Keti conf (2)
Keti conf (2)Keti conf (2)
Keti conf (2)
 
COMPETITION ACT, 2002
COMPETITION ACT, 2002 COMPETITION ACT, 2002
COMPETITION ACT, 2002
 
Competition Act, 2002
Competition Act, 2002Competition Act, 2002
Competition Act, 2002
 
Bid Rigging
Bid RiggingBid Rigging
Bid Rigging
 
Competition act
Competition actCompetition act
Competition act
 
Competition act
Competition actCompetition act
Competition act
 
Competition act
Competition actCompetition act
Competition act
 
Competition Assessment: The OECD Toolkit
Competition Assessment: The OECD ToolkitCompetition Assessment: The OECD Toolkit
Competition Assessment: The OECD Toolkit
 
competition act 2002
competition act 2002competition act 2002
competition act 2002
 
Competition act,2002
Competition act,2002Competition act,2002
Competition act,2002
 

Recently uploaded

8. SECURITY GUARD CREED, CODE OF CONDUCT, COPE.pptx
8. SECURITY GUARD CREED, CODE OF CONDUCT, COPE.pptx8. SECURITY GUARD CREED, CODE OF CONDUCT, COPE.pptx
8. SECURITY GUARD CREED, CODE OF CONDUCT, COPE.pptxPamelaAbegailMonsant2
 
LITERAL RULE OF INTERPRETATION - PRIMARY RULE
LITERAL RULE OF INTERPRETATION - PRIMARY RULELITERAL RULE OF INTERPRETATION - PRIMARY RULE
LITERAL RULE OF INTERPRETATION - PRIMARY RULEsreeramsaipranitha
 
BPA GROUP 7 - DARIO VS. MISON REPORTING.pdf
BPA GROUP 7 - DARIO VS. MISON REPORTING.pdfBPA GROUP 7 - DARIO VS. MISON REPORTING.pdf
BPA GROUP 7 - DARIO VS. MISON REPORTING.pdflaysamaeguardiano
 
Andrea Hill Featured in Canadian Lawyer as SkyLaw Recognized as a Top Boutique
Andrea Hill Featured in Canadian Lawyer as SkyLaw Recognized as a Top BoutiqueAndrea Hill Featured in Canadian Lawyer as SkyLaw Recognized as a Top Boutique
Andrea Hill Featured in Canadian Lawyer as SkyLaw Recognized as a Top BoutiqueSkyLaw Professional Corporation
 
CAFC Chronicles: Costly Tales of Claim Construction Fails
CAFC Chronicles: Costly Tales of Claim Construction FailsCAFC Chronicles: Costly Tales of Claim Construction Fails
CAFC Chronicles: Costly Tales of Claim Construction FailsAurora Consulting
 
一比一原版牛津布鲁克斯大学毕业证学位证书
一比一原版牛津布鲁克斯大学毕业证学位证书一比一原版牛津布鲁克斯大学毕业证学位证书
一比一原版牛津布鲁克斯大学毕业证学位证书E LSS
 
589308994-interpretation-of-statutes-notes-law-college.pdf
589308994-interpretation-of-statutes-notes-law-college.pdf589308994-interpretation-of-statutes-notes-law-college.pdf
589308994-interpretation-of-statutes-notes-law-college.pdfSUSHMITAPOTHAL
 
COPYRIGHTS - PPT 01.12.2023 part- 2.pptx
COPYRIGHTS - PPT 01.12.2023 part- 2.pptxCOPYRIGHTS - PPT 01.12.2023 part- 2.pptx
COPYRIGHTS - PPT 01.12.2023 part- 2.pptxRRR Chambers
 
IBC (Insolvency and Bankruptcy Code 2016)-IOD - PPT.pptx
IBC (Insolvency and Bankruptcy Code 2016)-IOD - PPT.pptxIBC (Insolvency and Bankruptcy Code 2016)-IOD - PPT.pptx
IBC (Insolvency and Bankruptcy Code 2016)-IOD - PPT.pptxRRR Chambers
 
pnp FIRST-RESPONDER-IN-CRIME-SCENEs.pptx
pnp FIRST-RESPONDER-IN-CRIME-SCENEs.pptxpnp FIRST-RESPONDER-IN-CRIME-SCENEs.pptx
pnp FIRST-RESPONDER-IN-CRIME-SCENEs.pptxPSSPRO12
 
一比一原版利兹大学毕业证学位证书
一比一原版利兹大学毕业证学位证书一比一原版利兹大学毕业证学位证书
一比一原版利兹大学毕业证学位证书E LSS
 
MOCK GENERAL MEETINGS (SS-2)- PPT- Part 2.pptx
MOCK GENERAL MEETINGS (SS-2)- PPT- Part 2.pptxMOCK GENERAL MEETINGS (SS-2)- PPT- Part 2.pptx
MOCK GENERAL MEETINGS (SS-2)- PPT- Part 2.pptxRRR Chambers
 
INVOLUNTARY TRANSFERS Kenya school of law.pptx
INVOLUNTARY TRANSFERS Kenya school of law.pptxINVOLUNTARY TRANSFERS Kenya school of law.pptx
INVOLUNTARY TRANSFERS Kenya school of law.pptxnyabatejosphat1
 
Negotiable Instruments Act 1881.UNDERSTAND THE LAW OF 1881
Negotiable Instruments Act 1881.UNDERSTAND THE LAW OF 1881Negotiable Instruments Act 1881.UNDERSTAND THE LAW OF 1881
Negotiable Instruments Act 1881.UNDERSTAND THE LAW OF 1881mayurchatre90
 
Essentials of a Valid Transfer.pptxmmmmmm
Essentials of a Valid Transfer.pptxmmmmmmEssentials of a Valid Transfer.pptxmmmmmm
Essentials of a Valid Transfer.pptxmmmmmm2020000445musaib
 
Transferable and Non-Transferable Property.pptx
Transferable and Non-Transferable Property.pptxTransferable and Non-Transferable Property.pptx
Transferable and Non-Transferable Property.pptx2020000445musaib
 

Recently uploaded (20)

8. SECURITY GUARD CREED, CODE OF CONDUCT, COPE.pptx
8. SECURITY GUARD CREED, CODE OF CONDUCT, COPE.pptx8. SECURITY GUARD CREED, CODE OF CONDUCT, COPE.pptx
8. SECURITY GUARD CREED, CODE OF CONDUCT, COPE.pptx
 
LITERAL RULE OF INTERPRETATION - PRIMARY RULE
LITERAL RULE OF INTERPRETATION - PRIMARY RULELITERAL RULE OF INTERPRETATION - PRIMARY RULE
LITERAL RULE OF INTERPRETATION - PRIMARY RULE
 
Sensual Moments: +91 9999965857 Independent Call Girls Vasundhara Delhi {{ Mo...
Sensual Moments: +91 9999965857 Independent Call Girls Vasundhara Delhi {{ Mo...Sensual Moments: +91 9999965857 Independent Call Girls Vasundhara Delhi {{ Mo...
Sensual Moments: +91 9999965857 Independent Call Girls Vasundhara Delhi {{ Mo...
 
BPA GROUP 7 - DARIO VS. MISON REPORTING.pdf
BPA GROUP 7 - DARIO VS. MISON REPORTING.pdfBPA GROUP 7 - DARIO VS. MISON REPORTING.pdf
BPA GROUP 7 - DARIO VS. MISON REPORTING.pdf
 
Andrea Hill Featured in Canadian Lawyer as SkyLaw Recognized as a Top Boutique
Andrea Hill Featured in Canadian Lawyer as SkyLaw Recognized as a Top BoutiqueAndrea Hill Featured in Canadian Lawyer as SkyLaw Recognized as a Top Boutique
Andrea Hill Featured in Canadian Lawyer as SkyLaw Recognized as a Top Boutique
 
CAFC Chronicles: Costly Tales of Claim Construction Fails
CAFC Chronicles: Costly Tales of Claim Construction FailsCAFC Chronicles: Costly Tales of Claim Construction Fails
CAFC Chronicles: Costly Tales of Claim Construction Fails
 
一比一原版牛津布鲁克斯大学毕业证学位证书
一比一原版牛津布鲁克斯大学毕业证学位证书一比一原版牛津布鲁克斯大学毕业证学位证书
一比一原版牛津布鲁克斯大学毕业证学位证书
 
589308994-interpretation-of-statutes-notes-law-college.pdf
589308994-interpretation-of-statutes-notes-law-college.pdf589308994-interpretation-of-statutes-notes-law-college.pdf
589308994-interpretation-of-statutes-notes-law-college.pdf
 
COPYRIGHTS - PPT 01.12.2023 part- 2.pptx
COPYRIGHTS - PPT 01.12.2023 part- 2.pptxCOPYRIGHTS - PPT 01.12.2023 part- 2.pptx
COPYRIGHTS - PPT 01.12.2023 part- 2.pptx
 
IBC (Insolvency and Bankruptcy Code 2016)-IOD - PPT.pptx
IBC (Insolvency and Bankruptcy Code 2016)-IOD - PPT.pptxIBC (Insolvency and Bankruptcy Code 2016)-IOD - PPT.pptx
IBC (Insolvency and Bankruptcy Code 2016)-IOD - PPT.pptx
 
Russian Call Girls Rohini Sector 6 💓 Delhi 9999965857 @Sabina Modi VVIP MODEL...
Russian Call Girls Rohini Sector 6 💓 Delhi 9999965857 @Sabina Modi VVIP MODEL...Russian Call Girls Rohini Sector 6 💓 Delhi 9999965857 @Sabina Modi VVIP MODEL...
Russian Call Girls Rohini Sector 6 💓 Delhi 9999965857 @Sabina Modi VVIP MODEL...
 
pnp FIRST-RESPONDER-IN-CRIME-SCENEs.pptx
pnp FIRST-RESPONDER-IN-CRIME-SCENEs.pptxpnp FIRST-RESPONDER-IN-CRIME-SCENEs.pptx
pnp FIRST-RESPONDER-IN-CRIME-SCENEs.pptx
 
Russian Call Girls Rohini Sector 7 💓 Delhi 9999965857 @Sabina Modi VVIP MODEL...
Russian Call Girls Rohini Sector 7 💓 Delhi 9999965857 @Sabina Modi VVIP MODEL...Russian Call Girls Rohini Sector 7 💓 Delhi 9999965857 @Sabina Modi VVIP MODEL...
Russian Call Girls Rohini Sector 7 💓 Delhi 9999965857 @Sabina Modi VVIP MODEL...
 
一比一原版利兹大学毕业证学位证书
一比一原版利兹大学毕业证学位证书一比一原版利兹大学毕业证学位证书
一比一原版利兹大学毕业证学位证书
 
MOCK GENERAL MEETINGS (SS-2)- PPT- Part 2.pptx
MOCK GENERAL MEETINGS (SS-2)- PPT- Part 2.pptxMOCK GENERAL MEETINGS (SS-2)- PPT- Part 2.pptx
MOCK GENERAL MEETINGS (SS-2)- PPT- Part 2.pptx
 
INVOLUNTARY TRANSFERS Kenya school of law.pptx
INVOLUNTARY TRANSFERS Kenya school of law.pptxINVOLUNTARY TRANSFERS Kenya school of law.pptx
INVOLUNTARY TRANSFERS Kenya school of law.pptx
 
Negotiable Instruments Act 1881.UNDERSTAND THE LAW OF 1881
Negotiable Instruments Act 1881.UNDERSTAND THE LAW OF 1881Negotiable Instruments Act 1881.UNDERSTAND THE LAW OF 1881
Negotiable Instruments Act 1881.UNDERSTAND THE LAW OF 1881
 
Rohini Sector 25 Call Girls Delhi 9999965857 @Sabina Saikh No Advance
Rohini Sector 25 Call Girls Delhi 9999965857 @Sabina Saikh No AdvanceRohini Sector 25 Call Girls Delhi 9999965857 @Sabina Saikh No Advance
Rohini Sector 25 Call Girls Delhi 9999965857 @Sabina Saikh No Advance
 
Essentials of a Valid Transfer.pptxmmmmmm
Essentials of a Valid Transfer.pptxmmmmmmEssentials of a Valid Transfer.pptxmmmmmm
Essentials of a Valid Transfer.pptxmmmmmm
 
Transferable and Non-Transferable Property.pptx
Transferable and Non-Transferable Property.pptxTransferable and Non-Transferable Property.pptx
Transferable and Non-Transferable Property.pptx
 

Competition.introduction.final

  • 2. Application of EU Competition law •EU consists of 27 Member States •EU and three other countries are part of European Economic Area (EEA) EU competition law applies to all countries in the EEA
  • 3. Institutions EU Institutions: •European Commission – enforces competition policy through directorate general (DG) – Can launch surprise investigations at company premises – Can require large mergers to be approved •EU Member States have their own competition laws and authorities •Companies must comply with competition laws of EU and Member States
  • 4. What is competition law? • Competition law exists to protect the process of competition in a free market economy – A system where the allocation of resources is determined solely by supply and demand in free markets • Competition wanted because of the market result it produces – Efficiency – Low prices – Innovations • Competition rules limits the freedom of the market players to protect the process of competition
  • 5. Economic efficiency - main objective of competition policy • Competition gives the best utilisation of scarce resources – Perfect competition v monopoly • Perfect competition – Pareto optimal use of resources » None could be made better of without someone being made worse of » Consumer welfare maximized – Productive efficiency » Constant pressure on costs » Cost reductions is the only means whereby firms can stay in business and increase profits
  • 6. • Monopoly – Leads to an inefficient allocation of resources » Quantity supplied less the quantity which would be supplied in a competitive market • Perfect competition, monopoly and competition in the real world – Workable competition
  • 7. ”workable competition” • The ECJs concept of ”workable competition” related to what competitin is inteded to achieve in the Community context – Not one of the concepts of ”workable competition” found in economic theory » But influenced by the theory • Concept of competition in the Merger Regulation compared: – Prohibits concentrations creating or strengthening a dominant position ”as a result of which effective competition would be significantly impeded in the common market”
  • 8. How to pursue the goals? • Prevent agreements restrictive of competition – Horisontal agreements (Among competitors) – Vertical agreements (between parties at different levels of the production or distribution chain) • Control market power and its abuse • Control oligopolistic markets • Prevent mergers which lead to a concentration in market power
  • 9. Overview of EU Competition Law Aspects of primary importance to business: •Article 101 TFEU makes illegal any agreement or concerted practice between undertakings that significantly restricts competition within EEA •Article 102 TFEU makes it illegal for dominant company to abuse its dominant position in market •Mergers EU competition law deals with anti-competitive agreements between companies and unilateral conduct of individual companies with dominant position
  • 10. Article 101 TFEU: Purpose and Rationale Article 101 prohibits agreements that disrupt free-market principles and hinder competitiveness Article 101 promotes independent decision-making over - •Pricing •Whether to sell in one country or several Decisions should be based on desire to attract new customers and retain existing ones Agreements that restrict two or more companies’ commercial options are likely to violate Article 101
  • 11. Article 101(1) TFEU • The following shall be prohibited as incompatible with the internal market: all agreements between undertakings, decisions by associations of undertakings and concerted practices which may affect trade between Member States and which have as their object or effect the prevention, restriction or distortion of competition within the internal market, and in particular those which:
  • 12. Article 101(1) TFEU (a) directly or indirectly fix purchase or selling prices or any other trading conditions; (b) limit or control production, markets, technical development, or investment; (c) share markets or sources of supply; (d) apply dissimilar conditions to equivalent transactions with other trading parties, thereby placing them at a competitive disadvantage; (e) make the conclusion of contracts subject to acceptance by the other parties of supplementary obligations which, by their nature or according to commercial usage, have no connection with the subject of such contracts.
  • 13. Article 101(2) TFEU 2. Any agreements or decisions prohibited pursuant to this Article shall be automatically void.
  • 14. Article 102 EC: Abuse of Market Dominance Article 102 is a companion of Article 101 •Directed at unilateral conduct of companies dominant in their market •Targets abuse of dominant position Abuse of a dominant position: Anti-competitive business practice undertaken to maintain or increase market position •Includes unfair pricing, restriction of production output, and imposing discriminatory terms on trading partners Violations of Article 102 can result in serious fines and other penalties
  • 15. Article 102 TFEU • Any abuse by one or more undertakings of a dominant position within the internal market or in a substantial part of it shall be prohibited as incompatible with the internal market in so far as it may affect trade between Member States.
  • 16. Article 102 TFEU • Such abuse may, in particular, consist in: (a) directly or indirectly imposing unfair purchase or selling prices or other unfair trading conditions; (b) limiting production, markets or technical development to the prejudice of consumers;
  • 17. Article 102 TFEU (c) applying dissimilar conditions to equivalent transactions with other trading parties, thereby placing them at a competitive disadvantage; (d) making the conclusion of contracts subject to acceptance by the other parties of supplementary obligations which, by their nature or according to commercial usage, have no connection with the subject of such contracts.
  • 18. Consequences of Non-Compliance Non-compliance has serious consequences: •Fines up to 10% of annual worldwide turnover •Liability in damages under national law •Voiding of contract •Criminal liability •Substantial expenditure of time and money •Bad publicity •Investigations by other competition authorities
  • 19. The sources of EC competition law • The Treaty Articles • Regulations – Merger regulation – Block exemptions • Judgements – European Court of Justice – Court of First Instance • Commission notices and guidelines • Commission decisions • Annual reports from the Commission • Other documents
  • 20. Some basic concepts • Market power • Market definition • Barriers to entry • S-C-P paradigm
  • 21. The concept of market power • Competition law concerned first and foremost with the problems that occur when a firm or two or more firms possess market power • A firm or firms that possess market power can enjoy some of the benefits available to the true monopolist – Market power presents undertakings with the possibility of limiting output and raising price, which are clearly harmful to consumer welfare
  • 22. Market Power • Market Power is the ability of a firm or a group of firms in a market to profitably raise prices, reduce quality, or slow down innovation for a significant period of time compared to these outcomes in a competitive market
  • 23. Analysis of Market Power • Market structure approach / Indirect approach • Market definition • Market shares • Market concentration • Barriers to entry and expansion • Perception of market participants • Competitive effects analysis / Direct approach • Predict post-merger price effects • Elasticity of demand
  • 24. Relevant market definition Commission Notice on the definition of relevant market for the purposes of Community competition law (also available in Latvian!)
  • 25. Relevant product market  'A relevant product market comprises all those products and/or services which are regarded as interchangeable or substitutable by the consumer, by reason of the products' characteristics, their prices and their intended use`
  • 26. Relevant geographic market  'The relevant geographic market comprises the area in which the undertakings concerned are involved in the supply and demand of products or services, in which the conditions of competition are sufficiently homogeneous and which can be distinguished from neighbouring areas because the conditions of competition are appreciably different in those area`
  • 27. Basic principles for market definition  Competitive constraints:  demand substitutability  supply substitutability  potential competition
  • 28. Demand substitution  starting from the type of products that the undertakings involved sell and the area in which they sell them,  additional products and areas will be included in, or excluded from, the market definition  depending on whether competition from these other products and areas affect or restrain sufficiently the pricing of the parties' products in the short term
  • 29. SSNIP test  small but significant and non-transitory increase in price (SSNIP)  hypothetical monopolist or cartel could profit from a price increase of 5% for at least one year (assuming that "the terms of sale of all other products are constant)?
  • 30. Demand substitution  Will the customers switch to readily available substitutes or to suppliers located elsewhere in response to a hypothetical small (in the range 5 % to 10 %) but permanent relative price increase in the products and areas ?
  • 31. Cellophane Fallacy  It may happen that using the SSNIP test one defines the relevant market too broadly, including products which are not substitutes  Du Pont (a cellophane producer) argued that cellophane was not a separate relevant market since it competed with flexible packaging materials such as aluminum foil, wax paper and polyethylene
  • 32. Critical loss  Where demand elasticities cannot be estimated  Defined as the maximum sales loss that could be sustained as a result of the price increase without making the price increase unprofitable.  Where the likely loss of sales to the hypothetical monopolist (cartel) is less than the Critical Loss, then a 5% price increase would be profitable and the market is defined
  • 33. Demand substitution example  Soft-drinks with flavour A vs those with flavour B?  Price = 10 (12 after the increase)  Sales = 1000 units (800 after the increase)  Variable costs:  remaining at the same level  Increase  Decrease
  • 34.  If the increase in price produces too much consumer substitution which is not compensated by the increase in price nor the reduction in costs?  The "market" formed by this only product is not "worth monopolising" as an increase in prices would not be profitable
  • 35. Supply substitution  suppliers are able to switch production to the relevant products and market them in the short term without incurring significant additional costs or risks in response to small and permanent changes in relative prices  Example: paper
  • 36. Potential competition  conditions of entry  Low barriers - potential competition will represent an effective competitive constraint  High barriers - potential competition is not likely to represent an effective competitive constraint
  • 37. Evidence – product dimension  Evidence of substitution in the recent past  Views of customers and competitors  Consumer preferences  Barriers and costs associated with switching demand to potential substitutes
  • 38. Evidence – geographic dimension  Past evidence of diversion of orders to other areas  Basic demand characteristics  Views of customers and competitors  Current geographic pattern of purchases  Trade flows/pattern of shipments  Barriers and switching costs associated to divert orders to companies located in other areas
  • 39. Barriers to entry • Barriers to entry hinders the emergence of potential competition which would otherwise constrain the incumbent undertaking • Crucial when determining market power – May have high market shares but no market power if there are no barriers to entry
  • 40. Analysing barriers to entry • Market definition and entry by production substitutes • Market conditions and historical entry • Assessment of absolute cost advantages • Assessment of strategic (first mover) advantages • Vertical foreclosure and exclusion • Predatory behaviour • Assessment of entry impediments
  • 41. S-C-P approach • Structure (competitive, monopolistic, monopolistically competitive, or oligopolistic) • - number of competitors, buyers, suppliers • - level of product standartisation • - barriers to entry • - scale economies, costs structures • Conduct (output decisions and pricing behavior, merger policies, R&D, investment & advertising policies) • Performance of the industry (production efficiency and profitability)
  • 42. Article 101(1) – the elements • The meaning of “undertaking” • Forms of co-operation caught – The meaning of agreement – Decisions by associations of undertakings – Concerted practices • “Object or effect the prevention, restriction or distortion of competition” • Effect on trade between member states • De minimis
  • 43. The concept of an “undertaking” • Article 101 (and 102) applies only to “undertakings” – Undertaking not defined in the EC Treaty • ECJs definition of an undertaking: – “the concept of an undertaking encompasses every entity engaged in an economic activity regardless of the legal status of the entity and the way in which it is financed” » Case 41/90, Höfner and Elsner v Macrotron, para 21
  • 44. • “Every entity” – The legal form of the entity irrelevant » All kind of companies » Persons • Self employed • Not employees (Opinion of GA Jacobs, case C-67/96, Albany) » Associations • “Associations of undertakings” directly caught • But can also be found to act as “undertakings” • Example: Co-operatives, P&I clubs • Exception: trade unions representing their members – The entity’s engagement in “economic activity” decisive
  • 45. • “Economic activity” – Any activity consisting in offering goods and services on a given market » Wide definition
  • 46. State bodies • Exercising official authority – ECJ: Article 101 does not apply to agreements concluded by bodies “acting in their capacity as public authorities and undertakings entrusted with the provision of a public service” (case 30/87, Bodson) – Includes tasks which are typical those of a public authority – Such tasks are not of an economic nature – Can to a certain extent be financed through fees of economic contributions • Engaging in economic activity – Will be regarded as an “undertaking” – How the public body is organised is not decisive
  • 48. Ten Highest Cartel Fines Per Case Since 1969 Year Case name Amount in € 2008 Car Glass 1 383 896 000 2009 Gas 1 106 000 000 2007 Elevators and Escalators 992 312 200 2010 Airfreight 799 445 000 2001 Vitamins 790 515 000 2007 Gas Insulated Switchgear 750 712 500 2008 Candle Waxes 676 011 400 2010 LCD 648 925 000 2010 Bathroom fittings 622 250 782 2006 Butadiene Rubber/Emulsion Styrene Butadiene Rubber 519 050 000
  • 49. Ten Highest Cartel Fines Per Company Since 1969 Year Case name Amount in € 2008 Saint Gobain (Car glass) 896.000.000 2009 E.ON (Gas) 553.000.000 2009 GDF Suez (Gas) 553.000.000 2001 F. Hoffmann-La Roche AG (Vitamins) 462.000.000 2007 Siemens AG (Gas insulated switchgear) 396.562.500 2008 Pilkington (Car glass) 370.000.000 2010 Ideal Standard (Bathroom fittings) 326.091.196 2007 ThyssenKrupp (Elevators and escalators) 319.779.900 2008 Sasol Ltd (Candle waxes) 318.200.000 2010 Air France / KLM (Airfreight) 310.080.000
  • 51. §1 – The Prohibition Rule (+ examples) Are prohibited as incompatible with the internal market: “all agreements between undertakings, decisions by associations of undertakings and concerted practices which may affect trade between Member States and which have as their object or effect the prevention, restriction or distortion of competition within the internal market (…)” §2 – The Rule of Nullity “Any agreements or decisions prohibited pursuant to this Article shall be automatically null and void” §3 – The Exception Rule §1 may be declared inapplicable to agreements which: 1. “contribute to improving the production or distribution of goods or to promoting technical or economic progress, 2. allow consumers a fair share of the resulting benefit, and which do not: 1. impose on the undertakings concerned restrictions which are not indispensable; 2. afford such undertakings the possibility of eliminating competition”
  • 52. Basic structure of analysis of Art.101 • Agreements violating Article 101(1) • and not capable of being exempted under Article 101(3) • are null and void (Article 101(2))
  • 53. Agreement: horizontal or vertical Step one • Agreement? • Between undertakings? • Appreciable effect on trade? • Object or effect? Step two • Derogations (Article 101 (3) TFEU) • Rule of reason (incl. block exemptions)
  • 54. Elements (step one) 1. “Agreements” 2. Between “undertakings” 3. Which have appreciable effect on intra-state trade 4. Which have as their object or effect the prevention, restriction or distortion of competition
  • 55. Unilateral practices/behaviour • Unilateral action NOT prohibited under Article 101 • Unilateral action is subject to rules of competition law only under Article 102 (abuse of dominance)
  • 56. Mergers • Are “worse” than agreements” • Joint ventures between the companies (depending on the level of integration): • Analysed under the merger rules; or • Analysed under the Article 101 rules Mergers Agreements Eliminate competition Reduce competition (preserve at least some level of competition) Leave permanent effect on the market Leave temporary effects on the market
  • 58. The concept of an “agreement” • ”Agreement”  widely construed – It is sufficient if the undertakings in question should have expressed their joint intention to conduct themselves on the market in a specific way » Alignment of the competition parameters available to them • “joint intention”  a legally binding agreement not necessary – The form of no importance (oral, signed, unsigned) – “gentlemen’s agreements” – The agreement does not have to be exhaustive » It is enough just to set the broad framework for the undertakings market conduct
  • 59. • The engagement of the parties in the agreement – It is enough to be partly engaged in the collaboration » Breach of contract regarding parts of the agreement – Passive “members” – An excuse if an undertaking has been “forced” into a cartel? • Collaboration through the establishment of a company (joint ventures)
  • 60. “Decisions of undertakings” • Collusion can take place through the medium of an association: Directly covered by art 101(1) – Makes it possible to hold associations directly liable • Association  widely defined • Decision  every statement made with the object or effect of influencing the commercial behaviour of the association’s members – Does not have to be binding (e g recommendations)
  • 61. “Concerted practices” • A form of co-ordination where undertakings, without concluding any sort of agreement or establishing a plan of action, knowingly substitute practical co-operation between them for the risks of competition – This criteria avoids that situations where companies collaborate without any kind of agreement but only on the basis of a common understand falls outside article 101(1) • It is contrary to the rules on competition for a producer to co-operate with his competitors, in any way whatsoever, in order to determine a co-operated way of action or to ensure its success by prior elimination of all uncertainty as to each others conduct regarding the essential elements of that action – ECJ, case 48/69, ICI v Commission
  • 62. Proving concerted practices • Direct or indirect contact • Meeting of minds or some kind of consensus – Exchange of information – Unilateral disclosure – Public announcements • Subsequent behaviour in the market • Indirect evidence of intention?
  • 63. Can a concerted practice be inferred from circumstantial evidence alone? • A question of the use of economic evidence in competition cases • Parallel market behaviour alone in itself not a concerted practice • BUT: It may however amount to strong evidence of such a practice if it leads to conditions of competition which do not correspond to the normal conditions of the market having regard to the nature of the products, the size and numbers of undertakings, and the volume of the said market power – ECJ, case 48/69, ICI v Commission • Oligopoly markets and economic evidence – Joint dominance
  • 64. The distinction between “agreement” and “concerted practices” • Overlapping concepts • No precise distinction – And no use for a precise distinction • “Concerted practice” important mainly where the Commission or the Courts is forced to rely upon circumstantial evidence alone
  • 67. Single economic unit doctrine • Two or more separate legal undertakings can be treated as on undertaking – if the undertakings “form an economic unit within which the subsidiary has no real freedom to determine its course of action on the market, and if the agreements or practices are concerned merely with the internal allocation of tasks as between the undertakings” » Case 30/87, Corinne Bodson • Agreements between two undertakings within a single economic unit not regarded as an agreement “between” undertakings – Escapes the prohibition in article 101(1)
  • 68. • The rationale: – No freedom to take decisions regarding the market conduct » Regarded as unilateral conduct » May be caught by article 102 if the undertaking has a dominant market position – Internal allocation of functions • The other side of the coin: – If a subsidiary engages in anti competitive agreements the mother company will also be regarded as part of the agreement
  • 69. • The test of control – If a parent company owns more than 50% of the shares in a subsidiary interdependency is presumed – Minority share holdings may also give control if combined with specific rights attached to them – One large shareholder and many small – Joint control (50/50) » Jointly controlled companies must belong to a single group of companies to be regarded as part of one economic unit
  • 70. The parent company’s responsibility for infringements committed by subsidiary • Case C-97/08 Akzo Nobel NV vs. Commission ”[W]here a parent company has a 100% shareholding in a subsidiary which has infringed the Community competition rules (…) there is a rebuttable presumption that the parent company does in fact exercise a decisive influence over the conduct of its subsidiary (…) The Commission will be able to regard the parent company as jointly and severally liable for the payment of the fine imposed on its subsidiary” 100% (or close to) of shares in subsidiary gives rise to presumption Parent company must show that the subsidiary acted independently on market – difficult (impossible?)! Maximum fine increases – 10% of group turnover If parent company has been involved in prior cartel – increase in fine Increased risk of being subject to specific increase for deterrence
  • 72. Cross-border trade effect • EU competition rules apply to practices which affect trade between Member States • Impact «within the internal market» («effects» doctrine) • EU-based firms reach an anticompetitive agreement over price/quantities on US markets – EU competition law is not applicable • Non-EU based firms reach an anticompetitive agreement over price/quantities on EU markets – EU competition law is applicable
  • 73. Cross-border trade effect 1. Must be appreciable 2. Means decrease, increase or simply diversion of trade
  • 74. Appreciable effect • The stronger the market position of the undertakings concerned, the more likely it is that an agreement or practice capable of affecting trade between Member States can be held to do so appreciably • BPB Industries and British Gypsum, Case T-65/89 • BUT: appreciability requirement was also fulfilled when the sales of the undertakings concerned accounted for about 5 % of the market • Miller, Case 19/77
  • 76. • “The distinction between „infringements by object‟ and „infringements by effect‟ arises from the fact that certain forms of collusion between undertakings can be regarded, by their very nature, as being injurious to the proper functioning of normal competition” • Competition Authority v BIDS and Barry Brothers, Case C-209/07
  • 77. Object cases • The object-category consist of “obvious restrictions of competition” • European Night Services v Commission, Joined cases T-374-375/94, 384/94 • The “object” rule can be described as a presumption rule: • if object is found, harmful effects on competition are presumed • certain types of agreements under normal market conditions always, or almost always, restrict competition
  • 78. Object cases • Horizontal agreements: • fixing prices • sharing markets • limiting outputs • Vertical agreements • Fixed and minimum resale price maintenance • Absolute territorial protection • Restrictions on passive sales • Other cases, listed in the “block exemptions”
  • 79. Effects cases • All cases, not falling within the “object box” • Negative effects on competition within the relevant market are likely to occur when: • the parties individually or jointly have or obtain some degree of market power and • the agreement contributes to the creation, maintenance or strengthening of that market power or allows the parties to exploit such market power.
  • 81. Economic theory usage • How can the agreement hinder competition? • Is collusion likely to occur on a given market? • Is cooperation between competitors likely to succeed or fail? Will it be easy or difficult?
  • 82. The prisoners’ dilemma Prisoner A Prisoner B Remain silent Confess Remain silent 0, 0 25, 15 Confess 15, 25 20, 20 Firm A Firm B Collude Cheat Collude 20, 20 15, 22 Cheat 22, 15 17, 17
  • 83. The prisoners’ dilemma • Prerequisites for a successful cartel and what complicates the cartel? • The problem of cheating? • Efficiency, savings from the horizontal cooperation
  • 84. What complicates collusion? • Demand side • Elastic demand (can the cartel set higher prices?) • Balancing buyer power? • Differentiated (vs homogenous products) • Demand booms as a characteristics of the market) • Non-stable demand
  • 85. What complicates collusion? • Supply side • Low seller concentration • Existence of competitors with elastic supply • Ease of entry • Cost assymmetries between cartel members • Prior collusion history on the market (more attention from competition authorities)
  • 86. Need for the possibility of high gains • Elastic and constant demand • Potential fines? (active/inactive competition authorities) • Members want and can cheat without being detected
  • 87. Organisation • Need to meet, agree • Need to communicate regularly • Many competitors vs “few” competitors • Reinhard Selton, the Nobel prize winner in “Four are few and six are many”: • Profitable to collude if less than 5 cartel members • More attractive to cheat if more than 5 cartel members
  • 88. Thank you! • Julija Jerneva • Mobile: +371 29131597