SlideShare a Scribd company logo
1 of 19
Practice Article


Introduction to normalization of demand
data – The first step in isolating the effects
of price on demand
Received (in revised form): 3rd September 2009




John D. Quillinan
is Executive Director of Analytics for Westgate Resorts, where his responsibilities include delivering analytics
to improve resort profitability, and implementing a revenue management system. John has over 25 years of
information technology and operational research experience. Revenue management, retail price optimization
and data analytics have been John’s focus the past 5 years. John’s most recently implemented price test
analytics were for Tractor Supply Company. Leveraging his revenue management background and strong
project management skills, John ushered in a price optimization system for the merchandise line of business
at Walt Disney Parks and Resorts. John also laid the groundwork for bringing in a placement optimization
system. In addition to creating the vision and plans for retail revenue management at Disney’s theme parks
and resorts, he assembled a strong team to lead the company through the development, implementation and
ongoing maintenance of these optimization systems. Before working for Disney, John was a Manager of
Operations Research at Norfolk Southern Corporation, and led a team of programmer analysts that
developed Intranet-enabled decision support applications. At Norfolk Southern, John and his team developed
and implemented a corporate forecasting system that is still in use today to assist Marketing with forecasting
volume and revenues. John also enjoyed a successful career in the airline industry, where he worked in the
Operations Research organizations at United Airlines, Delta Air Lines and Trans World Airlines over the
course of 10 years. John holds a Master of Science degree in Industrial and Systems Engineering from the
University of Southern California Los Angeles and a Bachelor of Science in Industrial Engineering from the
University of Tennessee Knoxville. He is a member of INFORMS, current Chair-Elect of the INFORMS Pricing
and Revenue Management Section and a Past Chair of the INFORMS Aviation Applications Section.
Correspondence: John D. Quillinan, 10046 Fox Meadow Trail, Winter Garden, Florida, USA

ABSTRACT This article is based on the presentation (Quillinan, 2008) delivered in Montreal at the
INFORMS Pricing and Revenue Management Section Conference in June 2008. We will introduce the concept
of data normalization in pricing. The fundamental first step in identifying optimal pricing is to determine the
price–demand relationship. The demand of a product is influenced by many explanatory variables such as
consumer traffic or number of visiting customers, demographics of consumers, weather, and product
availability. In order to extract the price–demand relationship, one must isolate the effect of price on demand
from the effects of other explanatory variables. We employ the normalization process to isolate the impact of the
significant explanatory variables on demand. In our study, normalization occurred on a weekly level, and within
demand zones. We aggregated daily demand and all explanatory variables – mostly visitation statistics and
demographics for a theme park and resort weekly. We grouped store locations to create demand zones for the
purpose of using only applicable explanatory variables. Using the techniques of normalization, model fit, as
measured by adjusted R2, improved dramatically when using all significant explanatory variables versus
consumer traffic only.
Journal of Revenue and Pricing Management (2010) 9, 4–22. doi:10.1057/rpm.2009.37;
published online 30 October 2009
Keywords: pricing; price elasticity; normalization; explanatory variables; demand drivers; retail




  & 2010 Macmillan Publishers Ltd. 1476-6930 Journal of Revenue and Pricing Management Vol. 9, 1/2, 4–22
                                         www.palgrave-journals.com/rpm/
Introduction to normalization of demand data




OPPORTUNITY                                                   We often refer to demand as being either elastic
‘Ceterıs paribus’ is fundamental to price
   ¯ ¯                                                        or inelastic. Elastic demand means that the
elasticity theory. Ceterıs paribus is Latin for
                     ¯ ¯                                      quantity demanded is sensitive to the price.
‘with other things [being] the same’ or ‘all                  Inelastic demand means that the quantity
other things being equal.’ For example, an                    demanded is not very sensitive to the price.
increase in the price of beef will result, ceteris               Demand also responds to exogenous and
paribus, in less beef being sold to consumers.                endogenous factors. Parameters or variables are
Putting aside the possibility that the prices of              said to be endogenous when they are predicted
chicken, pork, fish and lamb have simulta-                    by other variables in the model; variables are
neously increased by even larger percentages,                 exogenous if they are entirely outside the
or that consumer incomes have also jumped                     model. For example, a primary factor in any
sharply, or that CBS News has just announced                  business is the ‘traffic’, that is, the number of
that beef prevents AIDS, and so on – an                       guest/customers visiting a location or store.
increase in the price of beef will result in less             If more people visit a location, then generally
beef being sold to consumers.                                 the location sells more products. For the same
   Unfortunately, there are rarely instances in               price, demand is higher with higher traffic
which everything else remains the same.                       counts, and thus traffic can be an exogenous
Normalizing the demand data helps us satisfy                  variable. For many businesses, the traffic itself is
the ‘ceteris paribus’ requirement. We can                     also a function of the price: lower advertised
accomplish normalization through techniques                   prices drive more traffic into the store, and thus
such as ordinary least squares, whereby the                   traffic is also an endogenous variable. If this is
demand is regressed against the demand                        true for a business, then advertising versus
drivers. Price can be included in the model,                  traffic alone may need to be employed as an
or a two-stage approach can be taken whereby                  independent variable to isolate the price effect,
the normalized means from a primary model                     as advertised prices are having an impact on
without price as a covariate are regressed                    traffic. If independent variables, such as traffic
against price. By incorporating the drivers of                and advertised prices, are related, there are
demand for products into the modeling                         a variety of statistical procedures that you
process, we can more accurately model the                     might use to isolate the effects; Bascle (2008)
price–demand relationship for products.                       offers a methodology to control for endogene-
                                                              ity through the use of instrumental variables.
                                                                 The different types of consumers visiting
FACTORS INFLUENCING                                           a location may also influence a product’s
DEMAND                                                        demand; for instance, if more high-income
Will a change in the price of a good or service               consumers visit a location, we may find
change the quantity demanded? Understanding                   a higher proportion of high-end products
the price–demand relationship is the central                  sold. Consumer demographics capture the
goal to price a product or service correctly.                 intrinsic variability that influences price elasti-
At any given time, demand can be influenced                   city, and can vary over time, affecting the
by several factors beyond price. Traffic and                  quantity demanded for a product. In addition
customer demographics are just a couple of                    to the demographics of consumers varying over
factors that influence demand. The impact of                  time, consumer demographics typically vary
price on product demand is isolated when we                   by location.
identify significant explanatory variables (other                For any given traffic level or demographic
than price) and remove their effect.                          mix, we can make a difference to the bottom
   How sensitive is the quantity demanded to                  line by adjusting price to maximize profits.
a change in the price of the good or service?                 Understanding the factors that influence actual


              r 2010 Macmillan Publishers Ltd. 1476-6930   Journal of Revenue and Pricing Management   Vol. 9, 1/2, 4–22               5
Quillinan




                consumer behavior and applying the informa-                            called herding instinct. People tend to follow
                tion to maximize profits is the fundamental                            the crowd without examining the merits of
                value of normalization. There are numerous                             a particular object.
                studies on drivers that affect the demand of                       K   Prices of related goods: When a fall in the price
                products. We will discuss some of the factors                          of one good reduces the demand for another
                in the literature review; however, most of the                         good, the two goods are called substitutes
                factors were not applicable to specific imple-                         (for example, pork and beef). When a fall
                mentation.                                                             in the price of one good increases the
                                                                                       demand for another good, the two goods are
                                                                                       called complements (for example, cars and
                A LITERATURE REVIEW OF                                                 gasoline).
                FACTORS INFLUENCING                                                K   Availability of (number of and closeness of)
                DEMAND                                                                 substitutes: The greater the number of
                The literature was reviewed for studies of                             substitute products, the greater the elasticity.
                factors that influence product demand. We will                         The closer the substitutes for a good or
                touch on some of the noteworthy or more                                service, the more elastic demand will be in
                frequent factors found in the literature.                              response to a change in price.
                                                                                   K   Newness of the product: When first introduced,
                K    Product utility, that is, the usefulness of                       the demand for a product can be highly
                     product features, can influence product                           inelastic and gradually gain elasticity at
                     demand. Incremental utility can translate                         maturity. This reflects a compound of
                     into incremental demand.                                          primary demand of the product and impact
                     There are two measurable types of utility                         of cross price elasticity. Normalization of
                     gained from the use of any product or                             the price demand function must take the
                     service: utilitarian, which is the utility                        product’s lifecycle into account.
                     directly provided to the user, and conspic-                   K   Product presentation quantity and shelf space
                     uous, which is the utility provided to the                        allocation (placement): Altering the product
                     user as a result of being seen consuming the                      presentation quantity (within the same
                     product or service (Basmann et al, 1988).                         location and across multiple locations) will
                     The second type of utility is based on the                        alter demand. Dreze et al (1994) found that
                     concept of ‘conspicuous consumption’,                             product location had a large impact on sales,
                     which was coined by Thorstein Veblen                              whereas changes in the number of facings
                     (1912). Demand for some kinds of luxury                           allocated to a brand had much less impact
                     goods, like luxury automobiles, actually goes                     as long as a minimum threshold (to avoid
                     up as prices rise. When prices increase,                          out-of-stocks) was maintained.
                     demand increases instead of dropping or                       K   Degree of necessity or luxury: Luxury products
                     staying the same; this is referred to as the                      tend to have greater elasticity than neces-
                     Veblen effect. found evidence that offers                         sities. The demand for necessities tends to be
                     much support for the presence of status                           inelastic to price, whereas luxury goods and
                     motives in the behavior of women who buy                          services tend to be more elastic to price. For
                     cosmetics. Materialism, reference group and                       example, the demand for opera tickets is
                     even education have been associated with                          more elastic than the demand for urban rail
                     conspicuous consumption (Schor, 1998).                            travel. The demand for vacation air travel
                     Conspicuous consumption is also linked to                         is more elastic than the demand for business
                     the bandwagon effect, that is, purchasing a                       air travel.
                     good because others are purchasing that                           After examining 101 different studies on
                     good (Leibenstein, 1950). The effect is often                     gasoline, Espey (1996) found that while


6                   r 2010 Macmillan Publishers Ltd. 1476-6930   Journal of Revenue and Pricing Management   Vol. 9, 1/2, 4–22
Introduction to normalization of demand data




    gasoline demand appears to be inelastic                        negative, and that long-run price elasticity
    over the short term, over the long term                        was twice as large as the short-term price
    the effect is not the same. Goodwin et al                      elasticity.
    (2004) could not predict with absolute                         Some studies suggest that the demand for
    certainty what effect a rise in the price of                   alcohol is price inelastic; others suggest it is
    gas would have on quantity demanded.                           price elastic. This is a signal that perhaps the
    Goodwin et al observed that the demand                         demand for alcohol is being impacted by
    for fuel decreased by a greater percentage                     factors other than price that have not been
    than the volume of traffic. This is probably                   incorporated in demand models. Fogarty
    because all else was not equal (a violation                    (2004) concluded that the year of the study,
    of our ceteris paribus requirement). The                       the length of study, the per capita level of
    reason why fuel consumed decreases by                          alcohol consumption and the relative etha-
    more than the volume of traffic is probably                    nol share of a beverage are important factors
    that price increases trigger more efficient                    when explaining variations in estimates of
    use of fuel (by a combination of tech-                         the price elasticity of demand for alcohol.
    nical improvements to vehicles, more fuel-                     Again, the price elasticity of alcohol is being
    conserving driving styles and driving in                       impacted by other factors, which when not
    easier traffic conditions).                                    taken into account lead to poor estimates of
K   Proportion of income required by the item:                     elasticity.
    Products requiring a larger portion of the                 K   Time period consumed or time elapsed since a
    consumer’s income tend to have greater                         price change: Demand tends to be more elastic
    elasticity.                                                    in the long run than in the short term. The
    As incomes grow, increases in status con-                      more time consumers have to adjust to a
    sumption will be pursued. Chao and Schor                       price change, the more elastic the demand
    (1998) found that income and occupational                      for that good. Becker et al (1994) and Espey
    status were positively associated with the                     (1996) found this to be the case for cigarettes
    propensity to engage in status purchasing.                     and gasoline, respectively.
K   Habit-forming goods: Goods such as cigarettes                  Fibich et al (2005) found that price elasticity
    and drugs tend to be inelastic in demand.                      is very sensitive to the time that has elapsed
    Preferences are such that habitual consumers                   since the price change. The effect of
    of certain products become de-sensitized to                    reference price is most noticeable immedi-
    price changes. Cigarettes and alcohol have                     ately after a price change. A better estima-
    been the topics of numerous studies, includ-                   tion of elasticity can be derived when the
    ing their joint demand. Goel and Morey                         time dependencies are accounted for. Fibich
    (1995) concluded that cigarettes and liquor                    et al derive an expression for the price
    are substitutes in consumption; in other                       elasticity of demand in the presence of
    words, an increase in the price of cigarettes                  reference price effects that includes a
    leads to an increase in the consumption of                     component resulting from the presence of
    liquor and conversely.                                         gains and losses in consumer evaluations.
    Lyon and Simon (1968) reviewed results                     K   Permanent or temporary price changes: A 1-day
    from prior cigarette elasticity studies, which                 sale will result in a different response than
    vary widely, ranging from À0.10 to À1.48,                      a permanent price decrease of the same
    and suggested that temporal changes                            magnitude. Blattberg et al (1995) found
    may explain some of the variation. Becker                      that temporary retail price promotions cause
    et al (1994) found that the empirical results                  a significant short-term sales spike.
    tend to support the implication of addi-                   K   Price points: Schindler (2006) showed the 99¢
    ctive behavior that cross-price effects are                    price ending is a signal of low price appeal.


               r 2010 Macmillan Publishers Ltd. 1476-6930   Journal of Revenue and Pricing Management   Vol. 9, 1/2, 4–22               7
Quillinan




                Figure 1: Any change that alters the quantity demanded at every price results in shifts in the demand curve.


                   Decreasing the price from US$2.00 to $1.99                       increased by 222 per cent. Eighty-nine to
                   may result in greater increase in quantity                       seventy-one cents played on consumers’
                   demanded than decreasing it from $1.99 to                        left digit effect. Eighty-nine to sixty-nine
                   $1.98.                                                           cents played on consumers’ right digit signal
                   Thomas and Morwitz (2005) conducted                              as well as left digit effect to result in a
                   experiments with graduate students and                           phenomenal increase of 222 per cent.
                   showed that the greatest impact of price                     K   External factors: Weather (temperature and
                   ending comes when it changes the leftmost                        precipitation) can influence consumer pur-
                   digit in the price – $19.99 versus $20,                          chase behavior. Bottled water and flashlights
                   for instance, as opposed to $3.49 versus                         are typical pre-hurricane items. In 2004,
                   $3.50. ‘Generally, it can be said that this                      Wal-Mart (Hays, 2004) learned from Hurri-
                   happens because we read from left to right,’                     cane Charley demand data that sales for
                   Dr Thomas said, and we place extra                               strawberry Pop-Tarts increase seven times
                   importance on the first number we see.                           their normal sales rate ahead of a hurricane,
                   When he asked students to compare the                            and that beer was the top-selling pre-
                   prices of $99.99 with $150 and then                              hurricane item.
                   compare $100 with $150, they rated the                       K   Advertising: Becker and Murphy (1988)
                   gap between $99.99 and $150 as being                             have argued that advertising works by
                   significantly larger, even though there was                      raising marginal consumers’ willingness to
                   only a penny’s difference.                                       pay for a brand. Advertising actually raises
                   Blattberg and Wisniewski (1989) showed                           each individual consumer’s willingness
                   that when the price of margarine was                             to pay for a brand (Erdem et al, 2008),
                   lowered from 89 to 71 cents, sales volume                        and shifts the whole distribution of
                   increased 65 per cent, but when it was                           willingness to pay in the population (see
                   lowered from 89 to 69 cents, sales volume                        Figure 1).


8                r 2010 Macmillan Publishers Ltd. 1476-6930   Journal of Revenue and Pricing Management   Vol. 9, 1/2, 4–22
Introduction to normalization of demand data




Table 1: Theme park visitation statistics

Attendance – Visitor traffic at a theme park
Origin – Visitor’s permanent residence
Group type – Composition of the group visiting (family versus non-family)
Accommodations area – Where the visitor is staying overnight
Ticket type – Type of theme park ticket a visitor is using
Ethnicity – Ethnic origin of visitor
Household income – Household income of visitor
Last trip/repeat visitation behavior – Last time visitor was at theme park
Household segment – Segment into which household of a visitor falls


Table 2: Resort demographics

Resort population – Number of guests staying at a resort
Average length of stay by resort – Number of nights on average that a guest stays overnight
Average room rate by resort – Rate that a guest pays for room on average per night
Percent of children by resort – Based on the reported number of children staying at a resort



Although any of the above-described factors                         We started out with a larger list of business
could be examined to help isolate the effect of                  metrics, and narrowed down the lists tabulated
price on demand, for this study, in a theme                      in Tables 1 and 2. The demand drivers were
park and resort context, we focused on two                       identified through interviews with merchants as
exogenous explanatory factors, visitation                        well as insights from financial analysts support-
and demography. In our study, the normal-                        ing merchandise, and ultimately statistically
ization process was successfully applied to                      validated through multivariate regression ana-
the merchandise line of business, dramatically                   lysis. The demand drivers are often referred
improving the fit of the model relating demand                   to as explanatory variables or covariates in the
to price. The normalization process can be                       normalization.
applied to other lines of business, such as                         We selected different demand drivers for
restaurants or service industries, where demand                  sales of merchandise in the theme parks and
is price-able. Though the demand drivers may                     resorts. We will discuss each separately to give
change, the approach remains the same.                           the reader a background on these drivers. The
                                                                 reason behind the separation of demand drivers
                                                                 is that the theme park visitation statistics (see
THE STUDY: IDENTIFYING                                           Table 1) cannot be reasonably applied to the
APPLICABLE BUSINESS                                              sales of merchandise in resorts, because these
METRICS FOR DEMAND                                               statistics are collected through attendance-based
DRIVERS                                                          theme park research surveys. We carry out
The application of normalization to the sales of                 a different set of surveys on guests staying
merchandise at theme parks began with                            at resorts, and they therefore have their own
investigation of what business metrics were                      set of descriptive statistics. Because not all
collected. Many of these business metrics were                   resort guests visit the theme parks, it is
already accepted in terms of describing the                      inappropriate to infer that theme park visitation
cycle and trends of the theme park and resort                    statistics affect sales of merchandise at resort
businesses.                                                      locations.


                 r 2010 Macmillan Publishers Ltd. 1476-6930   Journal of Revenue and Pricing Management   Vol. 9, 1/2, 4–22               9
Quillinan




                 Visitation statistics                                           are family and non-family. Family subgroups
                 We intercepted guests visiting the theme parks,                 are based on the age of the oldest child. Non-
                 and asked a series of questions. Attendance is                  family subgroups are based on the age of the
                 the most important visitation metric. This is                   respondent.
                 the total number of ‘unique’ daily entries into a
                 park; it does not include re-entries, or cross-                 Accommodations area
                 overs between parks. Because the other visita-                  The Accommodations Area is where the visitor
                 tion statistics are reported at the individual park             is staying overnight. Broadly, we classify visitors
                 level, attendance is taken as the multiple-theme                as staying either ‘On’ or ‘Off ’ of the theme
                 park attendance. In this example, it is worth                   park-managed property/hotel.
                 noting that attendance is truly exogenous – it is
                 determined by factors unrelated to the prices                   Ticket types
                 of merchandise and foods; traffic to the theme                  Ticket types are classified according to the
                 parks as a whole is typically driven by academic                number of days over which a ticket can be used.
                 calendars (of school-age children, entrance
                 ticket prices and theme park/resort promo-
                 tions). As discussed earlier, this assumption may               Ethnicity
                 not be true for other retail businesses.                        Ethnic origin is classified into Caucasian,
                    Other visitation statistics include origin,                  African-American, Hispanic and All Other;
                 group type, accommodation area, ticket type,                    ethnic origin does not include international
                 ethnicity, household income, repeat visitation                  tourists.
                 behavior and household segment.
                                                                                 Household income
                 Origin                                                          Household income is based on the household
                 Origin is the guest’s permanent residence,                      income reported.
                 and is derived from the guest’s zip code.
                 The highest-level classifications for origin are                Last trip/repeat visitation behavior
                 Domestic Tourists, International Tourists and                   Repeat visitation behavior is when the guest
                 Local Residents. Domestic Tourists are from                     was on their last trip to the theme park; for
                 any of the 49 United States (not local).                        instance, was the guest here less than a year ago,
                 International Tourists live outside of the                      between 1 and 2 years ago, 2 and 3 years ago, 3
                 United States. Local Residents live locally.                    and 5 years ago, or more than 5 years ago. Last
                 Origin data are used to classify data such                      trip excludes first-timers.
                 as attendance. By being able to cut the data by
                 origin or even finer, we can see patterns
                                                                                 Household segment
                 emerge. In the normalization process, we do
                                                                                 Household segment is a classification of a
                 not use all of the highest-level classifications,
                                                                                 guest’s household based on life stage, and
                 but rather employ the classification that is most
                                                                                 visitation behavior. Similar to group type, life
                 significant and has the highest influence on
                                                                                 stage classification is based on presence of
                 demand. These classifications are determined
                                                                                 children in the household (family versus pre-
                 through statistical selection methods, such as
                                                                                 family and post-family) and ages of the children
                 backwards-stepwise linear regression.
                                                                                 or adults. There are six life stage segments:
                                                                                 Young Family, Tween Family, Teen Family,
                 Group type                                                      Pre-Family, Post-Family and Seniors.
                 Group type represents the composition of                           The visitation statistics discussed thus far are
                 the group visiting. The primary categories                      categories selected by the theme park’s research


10                r 2010 Macmillan Publishers Ltd. 1476-6930   Journal of Revenue and Pricing Management   Vol. 9, 1/2, 4–22
Introduction to normalization of demand data




department to measure and understand a theme                    process, and, typically, each guest receives a
park business. As a first pass, they are being                  room key with their name on it.
leveraged to normalize merchandise demand. We
did not create the categories and classifications               Weather statistics
for the normalization of merchandise demand.                    We introduced weather statistics, such as
   We did not use all classifications of the                    maximum temperature and total rainfall, which
categories in the normalization process. We                     are self-explanatory explanatory variables.
selected the following classifications of
the categories because of their statistical                     METHODOLOGY: AGGREGATION
significance:
                                                                OF DEMAND DATA
                                                                Normalization can occur on whatever level of
K   local residents;
                                                                time that the demand data and drivers co-exist.
K   families with children 0–13;
                                                                In the case of our study of merchandise
K   guests on 1-day park tickets;
                                                                demand, normalization occurred on a weekly
K   caucasian;
                                                                level. This is primarily because the theme park
K   household income > $60 000; and
                                                                demographics were deemed only significant at
K   guests whose last trip was less than 5 years ago.
                                                                the weekly level. We aggregated all data to the
                                                                weekly level, even though in some cases such as
Resort demographics                                             demand for merchandise products and park
Resort demographics, listed in Table 2, were                    attendance, the data were available on a daily
obtained from the resort occupancy statistics.                  basis. We selected weekly theme park demo-
While surveys of resort guests are conducted,                   graphics. We produced weather variables, such
these descriptive statistics were not employed in               as the minimum, maximum or average, to
the normalization owing to a more than 1-                       represent the entire week.
month lag in receiving this information, and to                    Normalization occurred within a demand
concerns that the statistics are not valid on a                 zone, or grouping of locations. The purpose
weekly level. The resort occupancy statistics                   was to use only applicable explanatory vari-
came directly from the hotel/resort operational                 ables. We used theme park visitation statistics to
systems for checking guests in and out.                         normalize merchandise demand observed
                                                                within the theme park. We used resort drivers
Resort population                                               to normalize merchandise demand observed at
Resort population is the number of guests                       resorts locations. We later aggregated the results
staying at a resort.                                            from the demand zones to the price zone level
                                                                for price differentiation.
Average length of stay                                             Stage-wise regression (Alley, 1987) is one of
Average length of stay is the number of nights                  the statistical approaches that are available for
on average that a guest stays overnight.                        use. Analysis of Covariance in conjunction
                                                                with meta-analysis techniques (Thompson and
Average room rate                                               Sharp, 1999) is just one approach of the many
Average room rate is the rate that a guest pays                 that are available. In the merchandise example,
for a room on average per night.                                we implemented a two-stage linear regression
                                                                with backward selection. The first-stage regres-
                                                                sion normalized the demand using all available
Percentage of children
                                                                explanatory variables in the following form:
Percentage of children is based on the reported
number of children staying at a resort; this
information is collected during the reservation                      ^
                                                                     d ¼ a þ b1 x1 þ b2 x2 þ Á Á Á þ bn xn þ e



                r 2010 Macmillan Publishers Ltd. 1476-6930   Journal of Revenue and Pricing Management   Vol. 9, 1/2, 4–22               11
Quillinan




                           ^
                 where d ¼ total demand owing to explanatory                     where Z ¼ profit function; P0 ¼ optimal price;
                 variables, excluding price effect; a ¼ base                     C ¼ cost (landed cost or procurement cost);
                 demand; bi ¼ rate at which demand changes                       ^
                                                                                 d0 ¼ normalized demand predicted with
                 with explanatory variable i; xi ¼ explanatory                   respect to price effect; j ¼ secondary demand
                 variables i; n ¼ number of explanatory variables                intercept; and d ¼ rate at which demand
                 i; and e ¼ error term.                                          changes with respect to price.
                     We then subtracted the fitted/predicted de-
                                                        ^
                 mand calculated from the first step dt from actual              NORMALIZATION USING ALL
                 observed demand, and added this residual to the
                                                                                 EXPLANATORY VARIABLES
                 average demand over the life of the product.
                                                                                 Normalization is a better alternative to how the
                             Pn
                                  dt                                             merchandise demand and price changes were
                         0
                       dt ¼  t¼i             ^               ^
                                     þ ðdt À dt Þ ¼ d þ ðdt À dt Þ               measured in the past. Historically, merchants in
                                n                                                the theme park business measured their success
                 where dt0 ¼ secondary stage demand at time t;                   based on per capita spending. Per capita is
                 dt ¼ actual observed demand at time t; dt0 ¼ - ^                simply the demand divided by the theme park
                 demand predicted by first-stage regression for                  attendance. ‘Per cap’ is the ‘average’ amount
                 time t, which is estimated using a þ b1x1t þ                    demanded per guest per day. All guests count,
                                           ¯
                 b2x2t þ ? þ bnxnt; d ¼ average demand over                      even those who do not spend any money at all.
                 life of the product; xjt ¼ explanatory variable j               Per capita is analogous to normalization using
                 at time t; i ¼ first time period; n ¼ number of                 attendance alone.
                 historical weeks available; and t ¼ time period.                                               d
                     In the second-stage regression, the secondary                                   Per cap ¼
                                                                                                               A
                 stage demand, which we refer to as the
                 normalized demand, was regressed against price                  where d ¼ demand; and A ¼ attendance.
                 to calculate the price coefficient, d.                             Attendance alone does not explain the
                                                                                 variability in merchandise demand as accurately
                                   ^
                                   d 0 ¼ j þ dP þ e                              as an estimate based on normalization. We find
                         ^                                                       that guests of different origins spend different
                 where d 0 ¼ normalized demand predicted with
                                                                                 amounts, and therefore per caps actually vary
                 respect to price effect; j ¼ base demand;
                                                                                 by origin. This is fairly intuitive if you think
                 d ¼ rate at which demand changes with respect
                                                                                 about it – let us use food and beverages as an
                 to price; P ¼ price; and e ¼ error term.
                                                                                 example. When you are a tourist, you are likely
                    The price coefficient is that amount by
                                                                                 to eat in the theme park, as you probably
                 which demand changes with regard to price. It
                                                                                 do not have anywhere else to go (unless you
                 is not the price elasticity estimate of demand,
                                                                                 have brought in food or are in a timeshare
                 re, that is the rate by which the percentage of
                                                                                 where you can cook). Conversely, when you
                 demanded changes with respect to percentage
                                                                                 are a local resident, you have the ability to eat
                 of change in price. The above equation
                                                                                 at home, and thus you might spend very little
                 estimated from the second-stage regression,
                                                                                 on food and beverages in the parks.
                 which represents the price-demand function,
                                                                                    To illustrate the need to normalize using more
                 was then used to calculate the price elasticity of
                                                                                 than attendance in the merchandise business, we
                 demand. This is a form of function that is
                                                                                 choose a commonly purchased product for
                 ultimately passed to the price optimization
                                                                                 obtaining character signatures: a vacation auto-
                 system to find the optimal price.
                                                                                 graph book. We compare (1) normalization using
                                      ^                                          attendance only (per cap); and (2) normalization
                      Max Z ¼ ðP0 À CÞd 0
                                                                                 using all explanatory variables including price.
                                ¼ ðP0 À CÞj þ dðP0 À CÞ2                         The measure of fit is the adjusted R2.


12                r 2010 Macmillan Publishers Ltd. 1476-6930   Journal of Revenue and Pricing Management   Vol. 9, 1/2, 4–22
Introduction to normalization of demand data




Figure 2: Normalization using Attendance Only.

   When we fit a statistical model of demand                   0 and 13; Family 0–13 ¼ percentage visitors that
using only attendance as the explanatory                       are families with the oldest child between ages
variable to our example product, the adjusted                  0 and 13; b5 ¼ rate at which demand changes
R2 is 0.64. In short, attendance helps to explain              with respect to location exposure; location ¼
approximately 64 per cent of the variation in                  percentage exposure that product is given
demand (Figure 2).                                             across locations; and e ¼ error term.
                                                                  When the demand was normalized using all
                 ^
                 d ¼ a þ bA þ e                                of the significant explanatory variables includ-
        ^                                                      ing price, five variables were significant: theme
where d ¼ total demand predicted; a ¼ base
                                                               park attendance, Caucasian, First Trip, Family
demand; b ¼ rate at which demand changes
                                                               0–13 and Location. This approach resulted in
with attendance; A ¼ attendance; and e ¼ error
                                                               an adjusted R2 of 0.85; 85 per cent of the
term.
                                                               demand variation is accounted for by the
    ^
    d ¼ a þ b1 A þ b2 Cauc þ b3 FirstTrip                      explanatory variables. Thus, the equation using
         þ b4 Family 0 13 þ b5 Location þ e                    additional variables improved the explanatory
                                                               power of the model from 64 per cent to 85
         ^
where d ¼ total demand predicted; a ¼ base                     per cent, a dramatic change (Figure 3).
demand; b1 ¼ rate at which demand changes                         The 21 per cent improvement in goodness of
with attendance; A ¼ attendance; b2 ¼ rate at                  fit for the autograph book is a non-refutable
which demand changes with respect to per-                      reason for including all significant explanatory
centage Caucasian visitors; Cauc ¼ percent                     variables versus attendance only.
Caucasian visitors; b3 ¼ rate at which demand                     Another example of where the goodness
changes with respect to percentage visitors on                 of fit measure improved by incorporating
First Trip; First Trip ¼ percentage visitors on                all significant explanatory variables was a
First Trip; b4 ¼ rate at which demand changes                  nighttime entertainment or ‘glow’ product.
with respect to percentage visitors that are                   Considering attendance only to explain the
families with the oldest child between ages                    variability in the demand, we end up with the


               r 2010 Macmillan Publishers Ltd. 1476-6930   Journal of Revenue and Pricing Management   Vol. 9, 1/2, 4–22               13
Quillinan




                 Figure 3: Normalization using all significant explanatory variables including price.




                 following model:                                                 Location ¼ percentage exposure that product
                                                                                  is given across locations.
                        ^
                        d ¼ 133:7688 þ 0:00008518 A þ e                               The first-stage-regression adjusted R2 for
                                                                                  this product went from 0.9 per cent for
                          ^
                 where d ¼ total demand predicted; A ¼                            attendance only to 54.7 per cent for a full
                 attendance level; and e ¼ error term.                            normalization model using all significant ex-
                    When we added the significant explanatory                     planatory variables.
                 variables to the model, we ended up with the                         In the second-stage regression for the sample
                 following ‘full’ model:                                          product in Figure 4, the normalized demand
                                                                                  is computed from the first-stage regression
                         ^
                         d ¼ À88:317348 þ 0:000102ÂA                              residuals and the means of the series. Figure 5
                                                                                  illustrates how the normalized demand for the
                               þ 3:646500838ÂCauc                                 superior model (that is, ‘full’ model) is then
                               þ 5:715628ÂTourist Ticket                          regressed against the price to arrive at the
                               þ 4:696201ÂLocal Resident                          predicted normalized demand with respect to
                                                                                  price.
                               À 6:176941ÂMax Temp
                               þ 5:757854ÂLocation                                        ^
                                                                                          d0 ¼ 372:0399 À 12:6762ÂP þ e
                                                                                          ^
                                                                                  where d 0 ¼ normalized demand predicted with
                         ^
                 where d ¼ total demand predicted; A ¼                            respect to price effect; and P ¼ price.
                 attendance; Cauc ¼ percentage Caucasian visi-                       Overall, there is a remarkable improvement
                 tors; Tourist_Ticket ¼ percentage of visitors                    in model fit across all items available for
                 on Tourist ticket; Local_Resident ¼ percen-                      normalization. The mean adjusted R2 goes
                 tage of visitors that are local residents;                       from 6 per cent to approximately 50 per cent
                 Max_Temp ¼ maximum temperature; and                              across the proportion of the products that are


14                 r 2010 Macmillan Publishers Ltd. 1476-6930   Journal of Revenue and Pricing Management   Vol. 9, 1/2, 4–22
Introduction to normalization of demand data




Figure 4: Normalization of Glow Product using Attendance Only and Full Model.




Figure 5: Second-stage regression results using Full Model.

available for normalization. We applied nor-                    improvement in adjusted R2 for a sample
malization to analyze every item that had at                    of the products impacted. Normalized
least 52 weeks of demand history and at least                   demand was calculated for the demand zone
one price change. Figure 6 illustrates the                      exhibiting the most sales per item; alternatively,


                r 2010 Macmillan Publishers Ltd. 1476-6930   Journal of Revenue and Pricing Management   Vol. 9, 1/2, 4–22               15
Quillinan




                 Figure 6: Distribution of adjusted R2 from Attendance Only to Full Model.




                 normalized demand can be weighted by the                        multiplied by the pre-price-change normalized
                 proportion of demand in a demand zone and                       demand, then the price change is concluded to
                 summed up across all groupings of locations to                  be a success. The caveat to this test is that
                 produce an estimate of normalized demand at                     product relationships should be taken into
                 the price zone level, which represents the                      consideration when evaluating a price change.
                 higher level of grouping of locations (above
                 demand zone) where price differentiation
                 occurs.                                                         NORMALIZATION REQUIRES
                    Normalization is the first step in isolating the             CONTINUAL PROCESS
                 effects of price on demand. After normalized                    IMPROVEMENT
                 demand, we can now go back and evaluate                         Normalization models must be updated reg-
                 whether or not a price change was successful.                   ularly. This requires a Continual Process
                 In Figures 2 and 3, the reader can see that                     Improvement. An organization that identifies
                 a price change occurred at about week 71.                       explanatory variables upon implementation and
                 A standard t-test was conducted on the means                    never goes back to update their models could
                 of the fitted (‘normalized’) demand before and                  be facing a disaster. In our example, annual
                 after the price change. If the means were                       audits to refresh models should be planned.
                 statistically different, then a simple comparison                  In addition to annual audits, there should be
                 of the pre- and post-price change normalized                    ongoing efforts to identify other explanatory
                 profit was carried out. If the normalized                       variables.
                 profit after the price change (that is, the new
                 price less cost of goods sold multiplied by the                 K   In the case of the glow product, park
                 post-price change normalized demand) was                            operating hours and total hours of darkness
                 greater than the old price less cost of goods sold                  during park hours were not available


16                r 2010 Macmillan Publishers Ltd. 1476-6930   Journal of Revenue and Pricing Management   Vol. 9, 1/2, 4–22
Introduction to normalization of demand data




    initially. However, later on, we evaluated                      location variable in the normalization mod-
    these data and found them to have merit in                      els, the average adjusted R2 was 0.35. Only
    the normalization process.                                      approximately 25 per cent of the models had
K   The number and type of locations at which a                     R2 higher than 0.5. After we added the
    product is available change often, and there-                   location variable, the model performance
    fore are likely to influence the demand for                     improved significantly (see Figure 7). The
    the product. We introduced an additional                        average adjusted R2 increased to 0.52. More
    explanatory variable, which represents the                      than 50 per cent of the models had adjusted
    availability of a product at different locations,               R2 that were higher than 0.5.
    to account for changes in product demand                    K   Big-box locations utilize ShopperTrak hard-
    owing to changes in a product’s availability                    ware, which effectively counts the number
    at different locations. The location variable is                of guests entering and exiting the location.
    the weighted number of locations at which a                     We leveraged the ShopperTrak guest counts
    product is available each week. We calculate                    collected on the hour to allocate labor
    the location variable for each item in each                     during heavy traffic periods. These guest
    demand zone. The weights for each location                      counts could be used in lieu of park atten-
    are the location’s percentage of contribution                   dance counts for demand at the big-box
    to total sales during the previous year. The                    store locations. ShopperTrak is common-
    weights are calculated at the sub-class level                   place at retail locations such as nationwide
    and applied to all items in the sub-class. We                   chains at indoor-shopping malls, and would
    update the weights every few months, to                         most likely be an ideal explanatory variable
    adjust for any location changes. Without the                    for a retailer to use in normalizing its




Figure 7: Distribution of adjusted R2- for Without and With Location Variable.



                r 2010 Macmillan Publishers Ltd. 1476-6930   Journal of Revenue and Pricing Management   Vol. 9, 1/2, 4–22               17
Quillinan




                      demand data. Improving upon the estimate                      K   Grad Night
                      of consumer traffic should have value for any                 K   Father’s Day
                      retailer.                                                     K   Sci-Fi Weekend
                                                                                    K   Summer Vacation
                                                                                    K   Independence Day
                 NEXT STEPS                                                         K   Labor Day
                                                                                    K   Food and Wine
                 Related products                                                   K   October Fest
                 The models presented in this article are                           K   Fright Fest
                 simplistic. Models that are more complex could                     K   Halloween
                 incorporate the prices of related goods, both                      K   Thanksgiving
                 complements and substitutes, and the number                        K   Holiday Season
                 of available substitutes. Market basket analysis is                K   Christmas
                 one technique that can help understand
                 demand dynamics.
                    An example of the price of related products                     Diagnostic tests
                 is how the price of the complement of a                            Finally, we have spent a lot of time explaining
                 princess costume, the tiara, wand and novelty                      how adding all of the significant explanatory
                 shoes impacts the demand of the princess cos-                      variables will result in better model fits. We do
                 tume. The prices of other characters’ costumes                     not want to lose sight of the importance of
                 may also influence the demand of other                             running diagnostics on our models. Therefore,
                 costumes. Costume ensembles may cannibalize                        our last next steps are to incorporate diagnostics
                 each other.                                                        in the regression processes. Some recom-
                                                                                    mended diagnostics are:

                 Special event indicators                                           K   Significance of explanatory variables: Are all of
                 In spite of our best efforts to identify operating                     the explanatory variables significant?
                 business metrics that explain merchandise                          K   Collinearity: Predictors that are highly colli-
                 demand, and incorporate product relationships,                         near, that is, linearly related, can cause
                 we will always fail at coming up with models                           problems in estimating the regression coeffi-
                 that result in high-adjusted R2. In some of                            cients. When more than two variables
                 these cases, further work with indicator vari-                         are involved, this is often called multi-
                 ables may be of some promise. Some products                            collinearity. The Variance Inflation Factor
                 are seasonal or driven specifically by recurring                       (VIF) is a good metric to use to evaluate
                 events. Some events that were identified in                            multi-collinearity. As a rule of thumb, a
                 theme park example are:                                                variable whose VIF values are greater than
                                                                                        10 may merit further investigation.
                 K    New Years Eves;                                               K   Normality: The errors should be normally
                 K    Presidents Day                                                    distributed – technically normality is neces-
                 K    Valentine’s Day                                                   sary only for the t-tests to be valid; esti-
                 K    Sports Weekend                                                    mation of the coefficients only requires that
                 K    Spring Break                                                      the errors be identically and independently
                 K    Easter                                                            distributed. The Kolmogorov-Smirnov test
                 K    Home and garden show                                              compares the cumulative distribution of the
                 K    Earth Day                                                         data with the expected cumulative Gaussian
                 K    Mother’s Day                                                      distribution, and bases its P-value on the
                 K    Memorial Day                                                      largest discrepancy.


18                   r 2010 Macmillan Publishers Ltd. 1476-6930   Journal of Revenue and Pricing Management   Vol. 9, 1/2, 4–22
Introduction to normalization of demand data




K   Homogeneity of variance (homoscedasticity): One             CONCLUSION
    of the main assumptions for the ordinary
    least squares regression is the homogeneity                 Greater confidence in price
    of variance of the residuals. If the model                  optimization
    is well fitted, there should be no pattern to               The two-stage regression methodology results
    the residuals plotted against the fitted values.            in a substantially improved model fit and thus
    If the variance of the residuals is non-                    in much stronger explanatory power. With this
    constant, then the residual variance is said                greater explanatory power, pricing analysts
    to be ‘heteroscedastic.’ There are graphical                have greater confidence in taking price recom-
    and non-graphical methods for detecting                     mendations from the price optimization. With-
    heteroscedasticity. The White Test (White,                  out this confidence, the pricing analyst could
    1980) tests the null hypothesis that the                    take the price in the wrong direction or perhaps
    variance of the residuals is homogenous.                    in the right direction but could conclude that
    Therefore, if the P-value is very small, we                 the price change had a negative effect.
    would have to reject the hypothesis and
    accept the alternative hypothesis that the
    variance is not homogenous.                                 Extensibility of normalization
                                                                The concept of normalization can be applied to
                                                                any line of business, where the demand is
Don’t lose sight of the big picture                             price-able. Though the demand drivers may
The pricing analyst should also incorporate                     change, the approach remains the same.
impacts on the category when evaluating the                        The end-user needs only to identify and
impact of price changes on individual products.                 apply those explanatory variables that are
The objective is to improve overall economics,                  unique to their business: the general demand
not the profitability of individual product lines.              drivers that might influence demand, particu-
An example: When a retailer increased the                       larly retail demand. In Table 3, I have attempted
price on a leading brand of detergent, he saw                   to enumerate and classify possible explanatory
a drop in the total gross margin; normally,                     variables, and identify which industries might
the pricing analyst would have concluded that                   benefit from them.
the price increase was a negative price test
and that the company should take price in
a different direction. However, when the                        Final diagnostic
analyst looked at the category sales, he noticed                While much of the process, for example, the
that another detergent whose price remained                     selection of explanatory variables and diagnos-
the same was gaining in higher gross margin                     tic tests, can be automated, this does not relax
owing to increased sales. He concluded that                     the need for a pricing analyst to ensure that the
the sales from the leading detergent had diver-                 inputs, that is, the explanatory variables, and
ted to the lower-quality detergent, on which                    the price optimization results, make sense.
the retailer happened to have a higher profit                   A pricing analyst provided three examples in
margin. At one point, the retailer was con-                     which price elasticities were out of kilter, and
sidering dropping the leading brand detergent,                  knowledge of consumer behavior or the
but the pro forma became more complicated.                      assortment provided additional insights for
The manufacturer of the leading brand deter-                    pricing decisions.
gent gave the retailer off-invoice promotions                      One example was a price recommendation
to keep their business; consequently, this allo-                for a princess lightchaser (a glow product). The
wed the retailer some options with product                      lightchaser was originally priced at $14,
pricing.                                                        changed to $15, later to $10, and then raised


                r 2010 Macmillan Publishers Ltd. 1476-6930   Journal of Revenue and Pricing Management   Vol. 9, 1/2, 4–22               19
Quillinan




                 Table 3: Covariates across industries

                 Seasonality covariates (most/all industries)
                   K   Fourier Filter-based Covariates (multiple yearly cycles)
                   K   Other Data-derived Covariates (such as monthly contribution ratios)
                   K   Day-of-Week Covariates
                   K   Holiday/Special Event 0/1 Indicator Covariates
                   K   Other User-defined Covariates

                 Customer-based covariates (Retail, hotel/cruise, distribution, services, casino, theme park, manufacturing)
                   K   Customer Demographics (total number of customers, Age/Financial Distribution, etc)
                   K   Customer Survey Information
                   K   Information on Prior Customer Relationships

                 Competition based covariates (Airline, petroleum, financial services, apartment leasing, distribution, any industry with
                 access to competitive data)
                    K    Market Strength Indices
                    K    Price or Volume of a Competitor’s key products
                    K    Your company’s Price Rank among competitors

                 Financial covariates (primarily financial services, petroleum, manufacturing, transportation, communications, others
                 where appropriate).
                   K    Gross Domestic Product (GDP)
                   K    Index of Leading Indicators
                   K    Gross National Happiness , a new concept relating happiness to economic growth
                   K    Population
                   K    Labor Force: Employment, Unemployment rate, Average Weekly earnings, Job security
                   K    Public Expenditure, Revenues, Budget Surplus and Deficit, National Debt
                   K    Personal Income, Expenditure, Savings
                   K    Broadband Internet Penetration
                   K    International: Balance of Payments (Current Account  Balance of Trade)
                   K    Productivity Survey
                   K    Manufacturing output, Capacity Utilization, Inventories
                   K    Money supply, Interest Rates (Fed Funds, Prime, Major Competitors), Yield on various financial
                        Instruments and Yield Curves.
                   K    Stock Market Indices (Dow-Jones Industrial Average, SP 500, etc)
                   K    Inflation, Consumer Price Index, Producer Price Index
                   K    New Home Sales
                   K    Retail Sales, Auto Sales
                   K    Lagging indicator, a historical indicator following an event that reacts slowly to economic changes
                   K    Genuine Progress Indicator, a concept in ecological economics and welfare economics that has been
                        suggested as a replacement metric for GDP
                   K    Spot market prices
                   K    Energy prices, supply and consumption (Source: US Department of Energy, Energy Information
                        Administration, http://eia.doe.gov)

                 Climate covariates (retail, healthcare, pipeline, any industry where relevant)
                   K   Daily Temperature (Low, High, Average, #consecutive cooling/heating days)
                   K   Rainfall




20                 r 2010 Macmillan Publishers Ltd. 1476-6930   Journal of Revenue and Pricing Management   Vol. 9, 1/2, 4–22
Introduction to normalization of demand data




back to $15. Using the price-demand history,                  pricing analyst otherwise, and prevented poten-
the system derived a price elasticity of                      tially disastrous price changes. In the end, the
0.0000175, and arrived at an ‘optimal’ price                  price-demand function from the normalization
of $400 000. Needless to say, the pricing analyst             process must pass the final diagnostic: the
declined the price recommendation, even                       pricing analyst sanity check.
though it had an expected revenue lift of $8.3
billion.
   Recent ‘flawed’ recommendations were                       ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS
produced for ponchos. After increasing the                    The model and graphs presented in this article are based
retail of ponchos by $1 – adults to $8 and youth              on fictitious demand data. We did not use actual products
to $7 – feedback from operations was received                 and demand data in the creation of the graphs. I thank the
that guests were balking at the price increases,              following individuals: Robert Shumsky for his encour-
                                                              agement, and valuable feedback throughout the referee
and purchasing a youth poncho instead.                        process; Utku Yildirim for his feedback on an early draft;
Ponchos in general were up in revenue. The                    the Merchandise Revenue Management and Pricing
systems generated pricing recommendations                     teams, in particular Ashley Bynoe and Tam Phan for
for ponchos based on an elasticity of À2.6 for                their valuable input, and Jacqueline Kappes for the pricing
adults and a positive elasticity for youth.                   analyst examples; and to my wife Kim Quillinan and April
                                                              Walsh for their review, suggestions and proofing.
Although these elasticities supported opera-
tional feedback, intervention by a pricing
analyst was still needed to understand the
poncho price change as a whole. Pricing                       REFERENCES
                                                              Alley, W.M. (1987) A note on stagewise regression. The American
decided to consolidate the price points and
                                                                 Statistician 41(2): 132–134.
tried lowering the price of both poncho sizes;                Bascle, G. (2008) Controlling for endogeneity with instrumental
unfortunately, the price test results were not                   variables in strategic management research. Strategic Organiza-
encouraging. After normalizing for attendance,                   tion 6(3): 285–327.
                                                              Basmann, R., Molina, D. and Slottje, D. (1988) A note on
weather, demographics and so on, there was no                    measuring Veblen’s theory of conspicuous consumption.
increase in demand. This supports the pricing                    Review of Economics and Statistics 70(3): 531–535.
analyst’s original hypothesis that ponchos are                Becker, G.S. and Murphy, K.M. (1988) A rational theory of
                                                                 addiction. Journal of Political Economy 6(4): 675–700.
inelastic and therefore price decreases do not                Becker, G., Grossman, M. and Murphy, K. (1994) An empirical
drive incremental revenue.                                       analysis of cigarette addiction. American Economic Review 84:
   The third and final example was related to                    396–418.
                                                              Blattberg, R.C., Briesch, R. and Fox, E.J. (1995) How
theme park novelty headwear, where a core
                                                                 promotions work. Marketing Science 14(3(2)): 122–132.
product had been increased from $9.95 to                      Blattberg, R.C. and Wisniewski, K.J. (1989) Price-induced
$11.95. At the same time, the novelty product                    patterns of competition. Marketing Science 8(4): 291–309.
line was expanded and a create-your-own hat                   Chao, A. and Schor, J.B. (1998) Empirical tests of status
                                                                 consumption: Evidence from women’s cosmetics. Journal of
was introduced. Both events led to cannibaliza-                  Economic Psychology 19(1): 107–131.
tion of the core product’s demand. As a result,               Dreze, X., Hoch, S.J. and Purk, M.E. (1994) Shelf management
the price optimization system recommended                        and space elasticity. Journal of Retailing 70(4): 301–326.
                                                              Erdem, T., Keane, M. and Sun, B. (2008) The impact of
a price decrease, because the core product                       advertising on consumer price sensitivity in experience goods
demand was down about 10 per cent. What the                      markets. Quantitative Marketing and Economics 6(2): 139–176.
system failed to take into account was that the               Espey, M. (1996) Explaining the variation in elasticity estimates of
                                                                 gasoline demand in the United States: A meta-analysis. Energy
total hat business was up; consequently, no
                                                                 Journal 17(3): 49–60.
decreases in retail prices of the core product are            Fibich, G., Gavious, A. and Lowengard, O. (2005) The dynamics
planned, as the quantity loss is believed stem to                of price elasticity of demand in the presence of reference price
from cannibalization and not the price increase.                 effects. Journal of the Academy of Marketing Science 33(1): 66–78.
                                                              Fogarty, J. (2004) The Own-price Elasticity of Alcohol: A Meta-
   In conclusion, the human mind caught                          analysis. The University of Western Australia. Department of
something about which the data told the                          Economics Working Paper, 04-01.




              r 2010 Macmillan Publishers Ltd. 1476-6930   Journal of Revenue and Pricing Management           Vol. 9, 1/2, 4–22            21
Quillinan




                 Goel, R.K. and Morey, M.J. (1995) The interdependence of               agement and Pricing Conference; 19 June, Montreal,
                    cigarette and liquor demand. Southern Economic Journal 62(2):       Quebec, Canada.
                    451–459.                                                         Schor, J.B. (1998) The Overspent American: Upscaling, Downshifting,
                 Goodwin, P., Dargay, J. and Hanly, M. (2004) Elasticities of road      and the New Consumer. New York: Basic Books.
                    traffic and fuel consumption with respect to price and income:   Schindler, R.M. (2006) The 99 price ending as a signal of a
                    A review. Transport Reviews 24(3): 275–292.                         low-price appeal. Journal of Retailing 82(01): 71–77.
                 Hays, C.L. (2004) What Wal-Mart knows about customers. The          Thomas, M. and Morwitz, V.G. (2005) Penny wise and pound
                    New York Times 14 November, http://www.nytimes.com/                 foolish: The left digit effect in price cognition. Journal of
                    2004/11/14/business/yourmoney/14wal.html.                           Consumer Research 32(01): 54–64.
                 Leibenstein, H. (1950) Bandwagon, Snob, and Veblen effects in       Thompson, S.G. and Sharp, S.J. (1999) Explaining heterogeneity
                    the theory of consumers’ demand. Quarterly Journal of               in meta-analysis: A comparison of methods. Statistics in
                    Economics 64(2): 183–207.                                           Medicine 18: 2693–2708.
                 Lyon, H. and Simon, J.L. (1968) Price elasticity of the demand      Veblen, T. (1912) The Theory of the Leisure Class: An Economic
                    for cigarettes in the United States. American Journal of            Study of Institutions. New York: Macmillan.
                    Agricultural Economics 50(4): 888–895.                           White, H. (1980) A heteroskedasticity-consistent covariance
                 Quillinan, J.D. (2008) Normalization of demand data: An                matrix estimator and a direct test for hetereoskedasticity.
                    introduction to normalization. INFORMS Revenue Man-                 Econometrica 48(4): 817–838.




22                 r 2010 Macmillan Publishers Ltd. 1476-6930     Journal of Revenue and Pricing Management       Vol. 9, 1/2, 4–22

More Related Content

What's hot

Module ii insulin therapy
Module ii insulin therapyModule ii insulin therapy
Module ii insulin therapymaqsood mehmood
 
NoSQL databases, the CAP theorem, and the theory of relativity
NoSQL databases, the CAP theorem, and the theory of relativityNoSQL databases, the CAP theorem, and the theory of relativity
NoSQL databases, the CAP theorem, and the theory of relativityLars Marius Garshol
 
What is a customer data platform (CDP)?
What is a customer data platform (CDP)?What is a customer data platform (CDP)?
What is a customer data platform (CDP)?Todd Belcher
 
Cure, Clustering Algorithm
Cure, Clustering AlgorithmCure, Clustering Algorithm
Cure, Clustering AlgorithmLino Possamai
 

What's hot (6)

OLAP
OLAPOLAP
OLAP
 
Module ii insulin therapy
Module ii insulin therapyModule ii insulin therapy
Module ii insulin therapy
 
NoSQL databases, the CAP theorem, and the theory of relativity
NoSQL databases, the CAP theorem, and the theory of relativityNoSQL databases, the CAP theorem, and the theory of relativity
NoSQL databases, the CAP theorem, and the theory of relativity
 
Graph mining ppt
Graph mining pptGraph mining ppt
Graph mining ppt
 
What is a customer data platform (CDP)?
What is a customer data platform (CDP)?What is a customer data platform (CDP)?
What is a customer data platform (CDP)?
 
Cure, Clustering Algorithm
Cure, Clustering AlgorithmCure, Clustering Algorithm
Cure, Clustering Algorithm
 

Similar to "Introduction to normalization of demand data

managerial economics profkanchan unit 2.pptx
managerial economics profkanchan unit 2.pptxmanagerial economics profkanchan unit 2.pptx
managerial economics profkanchan unit 2.pptxProf. Kanchan Kumari
 
Information Systems for Decision-MakingAssignment 1 The CEO’s.docx
Information Systems for Decision-MakingAssignment 1 The CEO’s.docxInformation Systems for Decision-MakingAssignment 1 The CEO’s.docx
Information Systems for Decision-MakingAssignment 1 The CEO’s.docxjaggernaoma
 
DEMAND AND SUPPLY ANALYSIS_ANABEL G BERNAL_BM 221.pptx
DEMAND AND SUPPLY ANALYSIS_ANABEL G BERNAL_BM 221.pptxDEMAND AND SUPPLY ANALYSIS_ANABEL G BERNAL_BM 221.pptx
DEMAND AND SUPPLY ANALYSIS_ANABEL G BERNAL_BM 221.pptxHopefulGratefulJing
 
Lecture 8 mba_marketing_management_-_pricing
Lecture 8 mba_marketing_management_-_pricingLecture 8 mba_marketing_management_-_pricing
Lecture 8 mba_marketing_management_-_pricingYousuffParvez
 
Pricing Strategy
Pricing StrategyPricing Strategy
Pricing StrategyDOST-TAPI
 
Marketing Chapter 20
Marketing Chapter 20Marketing Chapter 20
Marketing Chapter 20WanBK Leo
 
Microeconomics 365 Week 1
Microeconomics 365 Week 1Microeconomics 365 Week 1
Microeconomics 365 Week 1Stacey Troup
 
pricing presentation
pricing presentationpricing presentation
pricing presentationRiaz Khan
 
CONSUMER BEHAVIOUR II Unit 3.pptx
CONSUMER BEHAVIOUR II Unit 3.pptxCONSUMER BEHAVIOUR II Unit 3.pptx
CONSUMER BEHAVIOUR II Unit 3.pptxRahulVarma474903
 
Micro and macroeconomics
Micro and macroeconomicsMicro and macroeconomics
Micro and macroeconomicsNavneetKaur607
 
ECONOMICS_APPLICATION OR USES OF THE CONCEPT OF ELASTICITY-1.pptx
ECONOMICS_APPLICATION OR USES OF THE CONCEPT OF ELASTICITY-1.pptxECONOMICS_APPLICATION OR USES OF THE CONCEPT OF ELASTICITY-1.pptx
ECONOMICS_APPLICATION OR USES OF THE CONCEPT OF ELASTICITY-1.pptxAiswaryaLal11
 
Unveiling the Dynamics of Elasticity of Demand in Economics.pdf
Unveiling the Dynamics of Elasticity of Demand in Economics.pdfUnveiling the Dynamics of Elasticity of Demand in Economics.pdf
Unveiling the Dynamics of Elasticity of Demand in Economics.pdfEnterprise Wired
 

Similar to "Introduction to normalization of demand data (20)

Price Elasticity of Demand
Price Elasticity of DemandPrice Elasticity of Demand
Price Elasticity of Demand
 
managerial economics profkanchan unit 2.pptx
managerial economics profkanchan unit 2.pptxmanagerial economics profkanchan unit 2.pptx
managerial economics profkanchan unit 2.pptx
 
Information Systems for Decision-MakingAssignment 1 The CEO’s.docx
Information Systems for Decision-MakingAssignment 1 The CEO’s.docxInformation Systems for Decision-MakingAssignment 1 The CEO’s.docx
Information Systems for Decision-MakingAssignment 1 The CEO’s.docx
 
DEMAND AND SUPPLY ANALYSIS_ANABEL G BERNAL_BM 221.pptx
DEMAND AND SUPPLY ANALYSIS_ANABEL G BERNAL_BM 221.pptxDEMAND AND SUPPLY ANALYSIS_ANABEL G BERNAL_BM 221.pptx
DEMAND AND SUPPLY ANALYSIS_ANABEL G BERNAL_BM 221.pptx
 
Lecture 8 mba_marketing_management_-_pricing
Lecture 8 mba_marketing_management_-_pricingLecture 8 mba_marketing_management_-_pricing
Lecture 8 mba_marketing_management_-_pricing
 
Pricing Strategy
Pricing StrategyPricing Strategy
Pricing Strategy
 
Marketing Chapter 20
Marketing Chapter 20Marketing Chapter 20
Marketing Chapter 20
 
Albert
AlbertAlbert
Albert
 
Raj sourav
Raj souravRaj sourav
Raj sourav
 
Raj sourav
Raj souravRaj sourav
Raj sourav
 
Microeconomics 365 Week 1
Microeconomics 365 Week 1Microeconomics 365 Week 1
Microeconomics 365 Week 1
 
pricing presentation
pricing presentationpricing presentation
pricing presentation
 
CONSUMER BEHAVIOUR II Unit 3.pptx
CONSUMER BEHAVIOUR II Unit 3.pptxCONSUMER BEHAVIOUR II Unit 3.pptx
CONSUMER BEHAVIOUR II Unit 3.pptx
 
Pricing of a product
Pricing of a productPricing of a product
Pricing of a product
 
Micro and macroeconomics
Micro and macroeconomicsMicro and macroeconomics
Micro and macroeconomics
 
Industrial Economics
Industrial EconomicsIndustrial Economics
Industrial Economics
 
Best practice in pricing processes
Best practice in pricing processesBest practice in pricing processes
Best practice in pricing processes
 
Demand
DemandDemand
Demand
 
ECONOMICS_APPLICATION OR USES OF THE CONCEPT OF ELASTICITY-1.pptx
ECONOMICS_APPLICATION OR USES OF THE CONCEPT OF ELASTICITY-1.pptxECONOMICS_APPLICATION OR USES OF THE CONCEPT OF ELASTICITY-1.pptx
ECONOMICS_APPLICATION OR USES OF THE CONCEPT OF ELASTICITY-1.pptx
 
Unveiling the Dynamics of Elasticity of Demand in Economics.pdf
Unveiling the Dynamics of Elasticity of Demand in Economics.pdfUnveiling the Dynamics of Elasticity of Demand in Economics.pdf
Unveiling the Dynamics of Elasticity of Demand in Economics.pdf
 

"Introduction to normalization of demand data

  • 1. Practice Article Introduction to normalization of demand data – The first step in isolating the effects of price on demand Received (in revised form): 3rd September 2009 John D. Quillinan is Executive Director of Analytics for Westgate Resorts, where his responsibilities include delivering analytics to improve resort profitability, and implementing a revenue management system. John has over 25 years of information technology and operational research experience. Revenue management, retail price optimization and data analytics have been John’s focus the past 5 years. John’s most recently implemented price test analytics were for Tractor Supply Company. Leveraging his revenue management background and strong project management skills, John ushered in a price optimization system for the merchandise line of business at Walt Disney Parks and Resorts. John also laid the groundwork for bringing in a placement optimization system. In addition to creating the vision and plans for retail revenue management at Disney’s theme parks and resorts, he assembled a strong team to lead the company through the development, implementation and ongoing maintenance of these optimization systems. Before working for Disney, John was a Manager of Operations Research at Norfolk Southern Corporation, and led a team of programmer analysts that developed Intranet-enabled decision support applications. At Norfolk Southern, John and his team developed and implemented a corporate forecasting system that is still in use today to assist Marketing with forecasting volume and revenues. John also enjoyed a successful career in the airline industry, where he worked in the Operations Research organizations at United Airlines, Delta Air Lines and Trans World Airlines over the course of 10 years. John holds a Master of Science degree in Industrial and Systems Engineering from the University of Southern California Los Angeles and a Bachelor of Science in Industrial Engineering from the University of Tennessee Knoxville. He is a member of INFORMS, current Chair-Elect of the INFORMS Pricing and Revenue Management Section and a Past Chair of the INFORMS Aviation Applications Section. Correspondence: John D. Quillinan, 10046 Fox Meadow Trail, Winter Garden, Florida, USA ABSTRACT This article is based on the presentation (Quillinan, 2008) delivered in Montreal at the INFORMS Pricing and Revenue Management Section Conference in June 2008. We will introduce the concept of data normalization in pricing. The fundamental first step in identifying optimal pricing is to determine the price–demand relationship. The demand of a product is influenced by many explanatory variables such as consumer traffic or number of visiting customers, demographics of consumers, weather, and product availability. In order to extract the price–demand relationship, one must isolate the effect of price on demand from the effects of other explanatory variables. We employ the normalization process to isolate the impact of the significant explanatory variables on demand. In our study, normalization occurred on a weekly level, and within demand zones. We aggregated daily demand and all explanatory variables – mostly visitation statistics and demographics for a theme park and resort weekly. We grouped store locations to create demand zones for the purpose of using only applicable explanatory variables. Using the techniques of normalization, model fit, as measured by adjusted R2, improved dramatically when using all significant explanatory variables versus consumer traffic only. Journal of Revenue and Pricing Management (2010) 9, 4–22. doi:10.1057/rpm.2009.37; published online 30 October 2009 Keywords: pricing; price elasticity; normalization; explanatory variables; demand drivers; retail & 2010 Macmillan Publishers Ltd. 1476-6930 Journal of Revenue and Pricing Management Vol. 9, 1/2, 4–22 www.palgrave-journals.com/rpm/
  • 2. Introduction to normalization of demand data OPPORTUNITY We often refer to demand as being either elastic ‘Ceterıs paribus’ is fundamental to price ¯ ¯ or inelastic. Elastic demand means that the elasticity theory. Ceterıs paribus is Latin for ¯ ¯ quantity demanded is sensitive to the price. ‘with other things [being] the same’ or ‘all Inelastic demand means that the quantity other things being equal.’ For example, an demanded is not very sensitive to the price. increase in the price of beef will result, ceteris Demand also responds to exogenous and paribus, in less beef being sold to consumers. endogenous factors. Parameters or variables are Putting aside the possibility that the prices of said to be endogenous when they are predicted chicken, pork, fish and lamb have simulta- by other variables in the model; variables are neously increased by even larger percentages, exogenous if they are entirely outside the or that consumer incomes have also jumped model. For example, a primary factor in any sharply, or that CBS News has just announced business is the ‘traffic’, that is, the number of that beef prevents AIDS, and so on – an guest/customers visiting a location or store. increase in the price of beef will result in less If more people visit a location, then generally beef being sold to consumers. the location sells more products. For the same Unfortunately, there are rarely instances in price, demand is higher with higher traffic which everything else remains the same. counts, and thus traffic can be an exogenous Normalizing the demand data helps us satisfy variable. For many businesses, the traffic itself is the ‘ceteris paribus’ requirement. We can also a function of the price: lower advertised accomplish normalization through techniques prices drive more traffic into the store, and thus such as ordinary least squares, whereby the traffic is also an endogenous variable. If this is demand is regressed against the demand true for a business, then advertising versus drivers. Price can be included in the model, traffic alone may need to be employed as an or a two-stage approach can be taken whereby independent variable to isolate the price effect, the normalized means from a primary model as advertised prices are having an impact on without price as a covariate are regressed traffic. If independent variables, such as traffic against price. By incorporating the drivers of and advertised prices, are related, there are demand for products into the modeling a variety of statistical procedures that you process, we can more accurately model the might use to isolate the effects; Bascle (2008) price–demand relationship for products. offers a methodology to control for endogene- ity through the use of instrumental variables. The different types of consumers visiting FACTORS INFLUENCING a location may also influence a product’s DEMAND demand; for instance, if more high-income Will a change in the price of a good or service consumers visit a location, we may find change the quantity demanded? Understanding a higher proportion of high-end products the price–demand relationship is the central sold. Consumer demographics capture the goal to price a product or service correctly. intrinsic variability that influences price elasti- At any given time, demand can be influenced city, and can vary over time, affecting the by several factors beyond price. Traffic and quantity demanded for a product. In addition customer demographics are just a couple of to the demographics of consumers varying over factors that influence demand. The impact of time, consumer demographics typically vary price on product demand is isolated when we by location. identify significant explanatory variables (other For any given traffic level or demographic than price) and remove their effect. mix, we can make a difference to the bottom How sensitive is the quantity demanded to line by adjusting price to maximize profits. a change in the price of the good or service? Understanding the factors that influence actual r 2010 Macmillan Publishers Ltd. 1476-6930 Journal of Revenue and Pricing Management Vol. 9, 1/2, 4–22 5
  • 3. Quillinan consumer behavior and applying the informa- called herding instinct. People tend to follow tion to maximize profits is the fundamental the crowd without examining the merits of value of normalization. There are numerous a particular object. studies on drivers that affect the demand of K Prices of related goods: When a fall in the price products. We will discuss some of the factors of one good reduces the demand for another in the literature review; however, most of the good, the two goods are called substitutes factors were not applicable to specific imple- (for example, pork and beef). When a fall mentation. in the price of one good increases the demand for another good, the two goods are called complements (for example, cars and A LITERATURE REVIEW OF gasoline). FACTORS INFLUENCING K Availability of (number of and closeness of) DEMAND substitutes: The greater the number of The literature was reviewed for studies of substitute products, the greater the elasticity. factors that influence product demand. We will The closer the substitutes for a good or touch on some of the noteworthy or more service, the more elastic demand will be in frequent factors found in the literature. response to a change in price. K Newness of the product: When first introduced, K Product utility, that is, the usefulness of the demand for a product can be highly product features, can influence product inelastic and gradually gain elasticity at demand. Incremental utility can translate maturity. This reflects a compound of into incremental demand. primary demand of the product and impact There are two measurable types of utility of cross price elasticity. Normalization of gained from the use of any product or the price demand function must take the service: utilitarian, which is the utility product’s lifecycle into account. directly provided to the user, and conspic- K Product presentation quantity and shelf space uous, which is the utility provided to the allocation (placement): Altering the product user as a result of being seen consuming the presentation quantity (within the same product or service (Basmann et al, 1988). location and across multiple locations) will The second type of utility is based on the alter demand. Dreze et al (1994) found that concept of ‘conspicuous consumption’, product location had a large impact on sales, which was coined by Thorstein Veblen whereas changes in the number of facings (1912). Demand for some kinds of luxury allocated to a brand had much less impact goods, like luxury automobiles, actually goes as long as a minimum threshold (to avoid up as prices rise. When prices increase, out-of-stocks) was maintained. demand increases instead of dropping or K Degree of necessity or luxury: Luxury products staying the same; this is referred to as the tend to have greater elasticity than neces- Veblen effect. found evidence that offers sities. The demand for necessities tends to be much support for the presence of status inelastic to price, whereas luxury goods and motives in the behavior of women who buy services tend to be more elastic to price. For cosmetics. Materialism, reference group and example, the demand for opera tickets is even education have been associated with more elastic than the demand for urban rail conspicuous consumption (Schor, 1998). travel. The demand for vacation air travel Conspicuous consumption is also linked to is more elastic than the demand for business the bandwagon effect, that is, purchasing a air travel. good because others are purchasing that After examining 101 different studies on good (Leibenstein, 1950). The effect is often gasoline, Espey (1996) found that while 6 r 2010 Macmillan Publishers Ltd. 1476-6930 Journal of Revenue and Pricing Management Vol. 9, 1/2, 4–22
  • 4. Introduction to normalization of demand data gasoline demand appears to be inelastic negative, and that long-run price elasticity over the short term, over the long term was twice as large as the short-term price the effect is not the same. Goodwin et al elasticity. (2004) could not predict with absolute Some studies suggest that the demand for certainty what effect a rise in the price of alcohol is price inelastic; others suggest it is gas would have on quantity demanded. price elastic. This is a signal that perhaps the Goodwin et al observed that the demand demand for alcohol is being impacted by for fuel decreased by a greater percentage factors other than price that have not been than the volume of traffic. This is probably incorporated in demand models. Fogarty because all else was not equal (a violation (2004) concluded that the year of the study, of our ceteris paribus requirement). The the length of study, the per capita level of reason why fuel consumed decreases by alcohol consumption and the relative etha- more than the volume of traffic is probably nol share of a beverage are important factors that price increases trigger more efficient when explaining variations in estimates of use of fuel (by a combination of tech- the price elasticity of demand for alcohol. nical improvements to vehicles, more fuel- Again, the price elasticity of alcohol is being conserving driving styles and driving in impacted by other factors, which when not easier traffic conditions). taken into account lead to poor estimates of K Proportion of income required by the item: elasticity. Products requiring a larger portion of the K Time period consumed or time elapsed since a consumer’s income tend to have greater price change: Demand tends to be more elastic elasticity. in the long run than in the short term. The As incomes grow, increases in status con- more time consumers have to adjust to a sumption will be pursued. Chao and Schor price change, the more elastic the demand (1998) found that income and occupational for that good. Becker et al (1994) and Espey status were positively associated with the (1996) found this to be the case for cigarettes propensity to engage in status purchasing. and gasoline, respectively. K Habit-forming goods: Goods such as cigarettes Fibich et al (2005) found that price elasticity and drugs tend to be inelastic in demand. is very sensitive to the time that has elapsed Preferences are such that habitual consumers since the price change. The effect of of certain products become de-sensitized to reference price is most noticeable immedi- price changes. Cigarettes and alcohol have ately after a price change. A better estima- been the topics of numerous studies, includ- tion of elasticity can be derived when the ing their joint demand. Goel and Morey time dependencies are accounted for. Fibich (1995) concluded that cigarettes and liquor et al derive an expression for the price are substitutes in consumption; in other elasticity of demand in the presence of words, an increase in the price of cigarettes reference price effects that includes a leads to an increase in the consumption of component resulting from the presence of liquor and conversely. gains and losses in consumer evaluations. Lyon and Simon (1968) reviewed results K Permanent or temporary price changes: A 1-day from prior cigarette elasticity studies, which sale will result in a different response than vary widely, ranging from À0.10 to À1.48, a permanent price decrease of the same and suggested that temporal changes magnitude. Blattberg et al (1995) found may explain some of the variation. Becker that temporary retail price promotions cause et al (1994) found that the empirical results a significant short-term sales spike. tend to support the implication of addi- K Price points: Schindler (2006) showed the 99¢ ctive behavior that cross-price effects are price ending is a signal of low price appeal. r 2010 Macmillan Publishers Ltd. 1476-6930 Journal of Revenue and Pricing Management Vol. 9, 1/2, 4–22 7
  • 5. Quillinan Figure 1: Any change that alters the quantity demanded at every price results in shifts in the demand curve. Decreasing the price from US$2.00 to $1.99 increased by 222 per cent. Eighty-nine to may result in greater increase in quantity seventy-one cents played on consumers’ demanded than decreasing it from $1.99 to left digit effect. Eighty-nine to sixty-nine $1.98. cents played on consumers’ right digit signal Thomas and Morwitz (2005) conducted as well as left digit effect to result in a experiments with graduate students and phenomenal increase of 222 per cent. showed that the greatest impact of price K External factors: Weather (temperature and ending comes when it changes the leftmost precipitation) can influence consumer pur- digit in the price – $19.99 versus $20, chase behavior. Bottled water and flashlights for instance, as opposed to $3.49 versus are typical pre-hurricane items. In 2004, $3.50. ‘Generally, it can be said that this Wal-Mart (Hays, 2004) learned from Hurri- happens because we read from left to right,’ cane Charley demand data that sales for Dr Thomas said, and we place extra strawberry Pop-Tarts increase seven times importance on the first number we see. their normal sales rate ahead of a hurricane, When he asked students to compare the and that beer was the top-selling pre- prices of $99.99 with $150 and then hurricane item. compare $100 with $150, they rated the K Advertising: Becker and Murphy (1988) gap between $99.99 and $150 as being have argued that advertising works by significantly larger, even though there was raising marginal consumers’ willingness to only a penny’s difference. pay for a brand. Advertising actually raises Blattberg and Wisniewski (1989) showed each individual consumer’s willingness that when the price of margarine was to pay for a brand (Erdem et al, 2008), lowered from 89 to 71 cents, sales volume and shifts the whole distribution of increased 65 per cent, but when it was willingness to pay in the population (see lowered from 89 to 69 cents, sales volume Figure 1). 8 r 2010 Macmillan Publishers Ltd. 1476-6930 Journal of Revenue and Pricing Management Vol. 9, 1/2, 4–22
  • 6. Introduction to normalization of demand data Table 1: Theme park visitation statistics Attendance – Visitor traffic at a theme park Origin – Visitor’s permanent residence Group type – Composition of the group visiting (family versus non-family) Accommodations area – Where the visitor is staying overnight Ticket type – Type of theme park ticket a visitor is using Ethnicity – Ethnic origin of visitor Household income – Household income of visitor Last trip/repeat visitation behavior – Last time visitor was at theme park Household segment – Segment into which household of a visitor falls Table 2: Resort demographics Resort population – Number of guests staying at a resort Average length of stay by resort – Number of nights on average that a guest stays overnight Average room rate by resort – Rate that a guest pays for room on average per night Percent of children by resort – Based on the reported number of children staying at a resort Although any of the above-described factors We started out with a larger list of business could be examined to help isolate the effect of metrics, and narrowed down the lists tabulated price on demand, for this study, in a theme in Tables 1 and 2. The demand drivers were park and resort context, we focused on two identified through interviews with merchants as exogenous explanatory factors, visitation well as insights from financial analysts support- and demography. In our study, the normal- ing merchandise, and ultimately statistically ization process was successfully applied to validated through multivariate regression ana- the merchandise line of business, dramatically lysis. The demand drivers are often referred improving the fit of the model relating demand to as explanatory variables or covariates in the to price. The normalization process can be normalization. applied to other lines of business, such as We selected different demand drivers for restaurants or service industries, where demand sales of merchandise in the theme parks and is price-able. Though the demand drivers may resorts. We will discuss each separately to give change, the approach remains the same. the reader a background on these drivers. The reason behind the separation of demand drivers is that the theme park visitation statistics (see THE STUDY: IDENTIFYING Table 1) cannot be reasonably applied to the APPLICABLE BUSINESS sales of merchandise in resorts, because these METRICS FOR DEMAND statistics are collected through attendance-based DRIVERS theme park research surveys. We carry out The application of normalization to the sales of a different set of surveys on guests staying merchandise at theme parks began with at resorts, and they therefore have their own investigation of what business metrics were set of descriptive statistics. Because not all collected. Many of these business metrics were resort guests visit the theme parks, it is already accepted in terms of describing the inappropriate to infer that theme park visitation cycle and trends of the theme park and resort statistics affect sales of merchandise at resort businesses. locations. r 2010 Macmillan Publishers Ltd. 1476-6930 Journal of Revenue and Pricing Management Vol. 9, 1/2, 4–22 9
  • 7. Quillinan Visitation statistics are family and non-family. Family subgroups We intercepted guests visiting the theme parks, are based on the age of the oldest child. Non- and asked a series of questions. Attendance is family subgroups are based on the age of the the most important visitation metric. This is respondent. the total number of ‘unique’ daily entries into a park; it does not include re-entries, or cross- Accommodations area overs between parks. Because the other visita- The Accommodations Area is where the visitor tion statistics are reported at the individual park is staying overnight. Broadly, we classify visitors level, attendance is taken as the multiple-theme as staying either ‘On’ or ‘Off ’ of the theme park attendance. In this example, it is worth park-managed property/hotel. noting that attendance is truly exogenous – it is determined by factors unrelated to the prices Ticket types of merchandise and foods; traffic to the theme Ticket types are classified according to the parks as a whole is typically driven by academic number of days over which a ticket can be used. calendars (of school-age children, entrance ticket prices and theme park/resort promo- tions). As discussed earlier, this assumption may Ethnicity not be true for other retail businesses. Ethnic origin is classified into Caucasian, Other visitation statistics include origin, African-American, Hispanic and All Other; group type, accommodation area, ticket type, ethnic origin does not include international ethnicity, household income, repeat visitation tourists. behavior and household segment. Household income Origin Household income is based on the household Origin is the guest’s permanent residence, income reported. and is derived from the guest’s zip code. The highest-level classifications for origin are Last trip/repeat visitation behavior Domestic Tourists, International Tourists and Repeat visitation behavior is when the guest Local Residents. Domestic Tourists are from was on their last trip to the theme park; for any of the 49 United States (not local). instance, was the guest here less than a year ago, International Tourists live outside of the between 1 and 2 years ago, 2 and 3 years ago, 3 United States. Local Residents live locally. and 5 years ago, or more than 5 years ago. Last Origin data are used to classify data such trip excludes first-timers. as attendance. By being able to cut the data by origin or even finer, we can see patterns Household segment emerge. In the normalization process, we do Household segment is a classification of a not use all of the highest-level classifications, guest’s household based on life stage, and but rather employ the classification that is most visitation behavior. Similar to group type, life significant and has the highest influence on stage classification is based on presence of demand. These classifications are determined children in the household (family versus pre- through statistical selection methods, such as family and post-family) and ages of the children backwards-stepwise linear regression. or adults. There are six life stage segments: Young Family, Tween Family, Teen Family, Group type Pre-Family, Post-Family and Seniors. Group type represents the composition of The visitation statistics discussed thus far are the group visiting. The primary categories categories selected by the theme park’s research 10 r 2010 Macmillan Publishers Ltd. 1476-6930 Journal of Revenue and Pricing Management Vol. 9, 1/2, 4–22
  • 8. Introduction to normalization of demand data department to measure and understand a theme process, and, typically, each guest receives a park business. As a first pass, they are being room key with their name on it. leveraged to normalize merchandise demand. We did not create the categories and classifications Weather statistics for the normalization of merchandise demand. We introduced weather statistics, such as We did not use all classifications of the maximum temperature and total rainfall, which categories in the normalization process. We are self-explanatory explanatory variables. selected the following classifications of the categories because of their statistical METHODOLOGY: AGGREGATION significance: OF DEMAND DATA Normalization can occur on whatever level of K local residents; time that the demand data and drivers co-exist. K families with children 0–13; In the case of our study of merchandise K guests on 1-day park tickets; demand, normalization occurred on a weekly K caucasian; level. This is primarily because the theme park K household income > $60 000; and demographics were deemed only significant at K guests whose last trip was less than 5 years ago. the weekly level. We aggregated all data to the weekly level, even though in some cases such as Resort demographics demand for merchandise products and park Resort demographics, listed in Table 2, were attendance, the data were available on a daily obtained from the resort occupancy statistics. basis. We selected weekly theme park demo- While surveys of resort guests are conducted, graphics. We produced weather variables, such these descriptive statistics were not employed in as the minimum, maximum or average, to the normalization owing to a more than 1- represent the entire week. month lag in receiving this information, and to Normalization occurred within a demand concerns that the statistics are not valid on a zone, or grouping of locations. The purpose weekly level. The resort occupancy statistics was to use only applicable explanatory vari- came directly from the hotel/resort operational ables. We used theme park visitation statistics to systems for checking guests in and out. normalize merchandise demand observed within the theme park. We used resort drivers Resort population to normalize merchandise demand observed at Resort population is the number of guests resorts locations. We later aggregated the results staying at a resort. from the demand zones to the price zone level for price differentiation. Average length of stay Stage-wise regression (Alley, 1987) is one of Average length of stay is the number of nights the statistical approaches that are available for on average that a guest stays overnight. use. Analysis of Covariance in conjunction with meta-analysis techniques (Thompson and Average room rate Sharp, 1999) is just one approach of the many Average room rate is the rate that a guest pays that are available. In the merchandise example, for a room on average per night. we implemented a two-stage linear regression with backward selection. The first-stage regres- sion normalized the demand using all available Percentage of children explanatory variables in the following form: Percentage of children is based on the reported number of children staying at a resort; this information is collected during the reservation ^ d ¼ a þ b1 x1 þ b2 x2 þ Á Á Á þ bn xn þ e r 2010 Macmillan Publishers Ltd. 1476-6930 Journal of Revenue and Pricing Management Vol. 9, 1/2, 4–22 11
  • 9. Quillinan ^ where d ¼ total demand owing to explanatory where Z ¼ profit function; P0 ¼ optimal price; variables, excluding price effect; a ¼ base C ¼ cost (landed cost or procurement cost); demand; bi ¼ rate at which demand changes ^ d0 ¼ normalized demand predicted with with explanatory variable i; xi ¼ explanatory respect to price effect; j ¼ secondary demand variables i; n ¼ number of explanatory variables intercept; and d ¼ rate at which demand i; and e ¼ error term. changes with respect to price. We then subtracted the fitted/predicted de- ^ mand calculated from the first step dt from actual NORMALIZATION USING ALL observed demand, and added this residual to the EXPLANATORY VARIABLES average demand over the life of the product. Normalization is a better alternative to how the Pn dt merchandise demand and price changes were 0 dt ¼ t¼i ^ ^ þ ðdt À dt Þ ¼ d þ ðdt À dt Þ measured in the past. Historically, merchants in n the theme park business measured their success where dt0 ¼ secondary stage demand at time t; based on per capita spending. Per capita is dt ¼ actual observed demand at time t; dt0 ¼ - ^ simply the demand divided by the theme park demand predicted by first-stage regression for attendance. ‘Per cap’ is the ‘average’ amount time t, which is estimated using a þ b1x1t þ demanded per guest per day. All guests count, ¯ b2x2t þ ? þ bnxnt; d ¼ average demand over even those who do not spend any money at all. life of the product; xjt ¼ explanatory variable j Per capita is analogous to normalization using at time t; i ¼ first time period; n ¼ number of attendance alone. historical weeks available; and t ¼ time period. d In the second-stage regression, the secondary Per cap ¼ A stage demand, which we refer to as the normalized demand, was regressed against price where d ¼ demand; and A ¼ attendance. to calculate the price coefficient, d. Attendance alone does not explain the variability in merchandise demand as accurately ^ d 0 ¼ j þ dP þ e as an estimate based on normalization. We find ^ that guests of different origins spend different where d 0 ¼ normalized demand predicted with amounts, and therefore per caps actually vary respect to price effect; j ¼ base demand; by origin. This is fairly intuitive if you think d ¼ rate at which demand changes with respect about it – let us use food and beverages as an to price; P ¼ price; and e ¼ error term. example. When you are a tourist, you are likely The price coefficient is that amount by to eat in the theme park, as you probably which demand changes with regard to price. It do not have anywhere else to go (unless you is not the price elasticity estimate of demand, have brought in food or are in a timeshare re, that is the rate by which the percentage of where you can cook). Conversely, when you demanded changes with respect to percentage are a local resident, you have the ability to eat of change in price. The above equation at home, and thus you might spend very little estimated from the second-stage regression, on food and beverages in the parks. which represents the price-demand function, To illustrate the need to normalize using more was then used to calculate the price elasticity of than attendance in the merchandise business, we demand. This is a form of function that is choose a commonly purchased product for ultimately passed to the price optimization obtaining character signatures: a vacation auto- system to find the optimal price. graph book. We compare (1) normalization using ^ attendance only (per cap); and (2) normalization Max Z ¼ ðP0 À CÞd 0 using all explanatory variables including price. ¼ ðP0 À CÞj þ dðP0 À CÞ2 The measure of fit is the adjusted R2. 12 r 2010 Macmillan Publishers Ltd. 1476-6930 Journal of Revenue and Pricing Management Vol. 9, 1/2, 4–22
  • 10. Introduction to normalization of demand data Figure 2: Normalization using Attendance Only. When we fit a statistical model of demand 0 and 13; Family 0–13 ¼ percentage visitors that using only attendance as the explanatory are families with the oldest child between ages variable to our example product, the adjusted 0 and 13; b5 ¼ rate at which demand changes R2 is 0.64. In short, attendance helps to explain with respect to location exposure; location ¼ approximately 64 per cent of the variation in percentage exposure that product is given demand (Figure 2). across locations; and e ¼ error term. When the demand was normalized using all ^ d ¼ a þ bA þ e of the significant explanatory variables includ- ^ ing price, five variables were significant: theme where d ¼ total demand predicted; a ¼ base park attendance, Caucasian, First Trip, Family demand; b ¼ rate at which demand changes 0–13 and Location. This approach resulted in with attendance; A ¼ attendance; and e ¼ error an adjusted R2 of 0.85; 85 per cent of the term. demand variation is accounted for by the ^ d ¼ a þ b1 A þ b2 Cauc þ b3 FirstTrip explanatory variables. Thus, the equation using þ b4 Family 0 13 þ b5 Location þ e additional variables improved the explanatory power of the model from 64 per cent to 85 ^ where d ¼ total demand predicted; a ¼ base per cent, a dramatic change (Figure 3). demand; b1 ¼ rate at which demand changes The 21 per cent improvement in goodness of with attendance; A ¼ attendance; b2 ¼ rate at fit for the autograph book is a non-refutable which demand changes with respect to per- reason for including all significant explanatory centage Caucasian visitors; Cauc ¼ percent variables versus attendance only. Caucasian visitors; b3 ¼ rate at which demand Another example of where the goodness changes with respect to percentage visitors on of fit measure improved by incorporating First Trip; First Trip ¼ percentage visitors on all significant explanatory variables was a First Trip; b4 ¼ rate at which demand changes nighttime entertainment or ‘glow’ product. with respect to percentage visitors that are Considering attendance only to explain the families with the oldest child between ages variability in the demand, we end up with the r 2010 Macmillan Publishers Ltd. 1476-6930 Journal of Revenue and Pricing Management Vol. 9, 1/2, 4–22 13
  • 11. Quillinan Figure 3: Normalization using all significant explanatory variables including price. following model: Location ¼ percentage exposure that product is given across locations. ^ d ¼ 133:7688 þ 0:00008518 A þ e The first-stage-regression adjusted R2 for this product went from 0.9 per cent for ^ where d ¼ total demand predicted; A ¼ attendance only to 54.7 per cent for a full attendance level; and e ¼ error term. normalization model using all significant ex- When we added the significant explanatory planatory variables. variables to the model, we ended up with the In the second-stage regression for the sample following ‘full’ model: product in Figure 4, the normalized demand is computed from the first-stage regression ^ d ¼ À88:317348 þ 0:000102ÂA residuals and the means of the series. Figure 5 illustrates how the normalized demand for the þ 3:646500838ÂCauc superior model (that is, ‘full’ model) is then þ 5:715628ÂTourist Ticket regressed against the price to arrive at the þ 4:696201ÂLocal Resident predicted normalized demand with respect to price. À 6:176941ÂMax Temp þ 5:757854ÂLocation ^ d0 ¼ 372:0399 À 12:6762ÂP þ e ^ where d 0 ¼ normalized demand predicted with ^ where d ¼ total demand predicted; A ¼ respect to price effect; and P ¼ price. attendance; Cauc ¼ percentage Caucasian visi- Overall, there is a remarkable improvement tors; Tourist_Ticket ¼ percentage of visitors in model fit across all items available for on Tourist ticket; Local_Resident ¼ percen- normalization. The mean adjusted R2 goes tage of visitors that are local residents; from 6 per cent to approximately 50 per cent Max_Temp ¼ maximum temperature; and across the proportion of the products that are 14 r 2010 Macmillan Publishers Ltd. 1476-6930 Journal of Revenue and Pricing Management Vol. 9, 1/2, 4–22
  • 12. Introduction to normalization of demand data Figure 4: Normalization of Glow Product using Attendance Only and Full Model. Figure 5: Second-stage regression results using Full Model. available for normalization. We applied nor- improvement in adjusted R2 for a sample malization to analyze every item that had at of the products impacted. Normalized least 52 weeks of demand history and at least demand was calculated for the demand zone one price change. Figure 6 illustrates the exhibiting the most sales per item; alternatively, r 2010 Macmillan Publishers Ltd. 1476-6930 Journal of Revenue and Pricing Management Vol. 9, 1/2, 4–22 15
  • 13. Quillinan Figure 6: Distribution of adjusted R2 from Attendance Only to Full Model. normalized demand can be weighted by the multiplied by the pre-price-change normalized proportion of demand in a demand zone and demand, then the price change is concluded to summed up across all groupings of locations to be a success. The caveat to this test is that produce an estimate of normalized demand at product relationships should be taken into the price zone level, which represents the consideration when evaluating a price change. higher level of grouping of locations (above demand zone) where price differentiation occurs. NORMALIZATION REQUIRES Normalization is the first step in isolating the CONTINUAL PROCESS effects of price on demand. After normalized IMPROVEMENT demand, we can now go back and evaluate Normalization models must be updated reg- whether or not a price change was successful. ularly. This requires a Continual Process In Figures 2 and 3, the reader can see that Improvement. An organization that identifies a price change occurred at about week 71. explanatory variables upon implementation and A standard t-test was conducted on the means never goes back to update their models could of the fitted (‘normalized’) demand before and be facing a disaster. In our example, annual after the price change. If the means were audits to refresh models should be planned. statistically different, then a simple comparison In addition to annual audits, there should be of the pre- and post-price change normalized ongoing efforts to identify other explanatory profit was carried out. If the normalized variables. profit after the price change (that is, the new price less cost of goods sold multiplied by the K In the case of the glow product, park post-price change normalized demand) was operating hours and total hours of darkness greater than the old price less cost of goods sold during park hours were not available 16 r 2010 Macmillan Publishers Ltd. 1476-6930 Journal of Revenue and Pricing Management Vol. 9, 1/2, 4–22
  • 14. Introduction to normalization of demand data initially. However, later on, we evaluated location variable in the normalization mod- these data and found them to have merit in els, the average adjusted R2 was 0.35. Only the normalization process. approximately 25 per cent of the models had K The number and type of locations at which a R2 higher than 0.5. After we added the product is available change often, and there- location variable, the model performance fore are likely to influence the demand for improved significantly (see Figure 7). The the product. We introduced an additional average adjusted R2 increased to 0.52. More explanatory variable, which represents the than 50 per cent of the models had adjusted availability of a product at different locations, R2 that were higher than 0.5. to account for changes in product demand K Big-box locations utilize ShopperTrak hard- owing to changes in a product’s availability ware, which effectively counts the number at different locations. The location variable is of guests entering and exiting the location. the weighted number of locations at which a We leveraged the ShopperTrak guest counts product is available each week. We calculate collected on the hour to allocate labor the location variable for each item in each during heavy traffic periods. These guest demand zone. The weights for each location counts could be used in lieu of park atten- are the location’s percentage of contribution dance counts for demand at the big-box to total sales during the previous year. The store locations. ShopperTrak is common- weights are calculated at the sub-class level place at retail locations such as nationwide and applied to all items in the sub-class. We chains at indoor-shopping malls, and would update the weights every few months, to most likely be an ideal explanatory variable adjust for any location changes. Without the for a retailer to use in normalizing its Figure 7: Distribution of adjusted R2- for Without and With Location Variable. r 2010 Macmillan Publishers Ltd. 1476-6930 Journal of Revenue and Pricing Management Vol. 9, 1/2, 4–22 17
  • 15. Quillinan demand data. Improving upon the estimate K Grad Night of consumer traffic should have value for any K Father’s Day retailer. K Sci-Fi Weekend K Summer Vacation K Independence Day NEXT STEPS K Labor Day K Food and Wine Related products K October Fest The models presented in this article are K Fright Fest simplistic. Models that are more complex could K Halloween incorporate the prices of related goods, both K Thanksgiving complements and substitutes, and the number K Holiday Season of available substitutes. Market basket analysis is K Christmas one technique that can help understand demand dynamics. An example of the price of related products Diagnostic tests is how the price of the complement of a Finally, we have spent a lot of time explaining princess costume, the tiara, wand and novelty how adding all of the significant explanatory shoes impacts the demand of the princess cos- variables will result in better model fits. We do tume. The prices of other characters’ costumes not want to lose sight of the importance of may also influence the demand of other running diagnostics on our models. Therefore, costumes. Costume ensembles may cannibalize our last next steps are to incorporate diagnostics each other. in the regression processes. Some recom- mended diagnostics are: Special event indicators K Significance of explanatory variables: Are all of In spite of our best efforts to identify operating the explanatory variables significant? business metrics that explain merchandise K Collinearity: Predictors that are highly colli- demand, and incorporate product relationships, near, that is, linearly related, can cause we will always fail at coming up with models problems in estimating the regression coeffi- that result in high-adjusted R2. In some of cients. When more than two variables these cases, further work with indicator vari- are involved, this is often called multi- ables may be of some promise. Some products collinearity. The Variance Inflation Factor are seasonal or driven specifically by recurring (VIF) is a good metric to use to evaluate events. Some events that were identified in multi-collinearity. As a rule of thumb, a theme park example are: variable whose VIF values are greater than 10 may merit further investigation. K New Years Eves; K Normality: The errors should be normally K Presidents Day distributed – technically normality is neces- K Valentine’s Day sary only for the t-tests to be valid; esti- K Sports Weekend mation of the coefficients only requires that K Spring Break the errors be identically and independently K Easter distributed. The Kolmogorov-Smirnov test K Home and garden show compares the cumulative distribution of the K Earth Day data with the expected cumulative Gaussian K Mother’s Day distribution, and bases its P-value on the K Memorial Day largest discrepancy. 18 r 2010 Macmillan Publishers Ltd. 1476-6930 Journal of Revenue and Pricing Management Vol. 9, 1/2, 4–22
  • 16. Introduction to normalization of demand data K Homogeneity of variance (homoscedasticity): One CONCLUSION of the main assumptions for the ordinary least squares regression is the homogeneity Greater confidence in price of variance of the residuals. If the model optimization is well fitted, there should be no pattern to The two-stage regression methodology results the residuals plotted against the fitted values. in a substantially improved model fit and thus If the variance of the residuals is non- in much stronger explanatory power. With this constant, then the residual variance is said greater explanatory power, pricing analysts to be ‘heteroscedastic.’ There are graphical have greater confidence in taking price recom- and non-graphical methods for detecting mendations from the price optimization. With- heteroscedasticity. The White Test (White, out this confidence, the pricing analyst could 1980) tests the null hypothesis that the take the price in the wrong direction or perhaps variance of the residuals is homogenous. in the right direction but could conclude that Therefore, if the P-value is very small, we the price change had a negative effect. would have to reject the hypothesis and accept the alternative hypothesis that the variance is not homogenous. Extensibility of normalization The concept of normalization can be applied to any line of business, where the demand is Don’t lose sight of the big picture price-able. Though the demand drivers may The pricing analyst should also incorporate change, the approach remains the same. impacts on the category when evaluating the The end-user needs only to identify and impact of price changes on individual products. apply those explanatory variables that are The objective is to improve overall economics, unique to their business: the general demand not the profitability of individual product lines. drivers that might influence demand, particu- An example: When a retailer increased the larly retail demand. In Table 3, I have attempted price on a leading brand of detergent, he saw to enumerate and classify possible explanatory a drop in the total gross margin; normally, variables, and identify which industries might the pricing analyst would have concluded that benefit from them. the price increase was a negative price test and that the company should take price in a different direction. However, when the Final diagnostic analyst looked at the category sales, he noticed While much of the process, for example, the that another detergent whose price remained selection of explanatory variables and diagnos- the same was gaining in higher gross margin tic tests, can be automated, this does not relax owing to increased sales. He concluded that the need for a pricing analyst to ensure that the the sales from the leading detergent had diver- inputs, that is, the explanatory variables, and ted to the lower-quality detergent, on which the price optimization results, make sense. the retailer happened to have a higher profit A pricing analyst provided three examples in margin. At one point, the retailer was con- which price elasticities were out of kilter, and sidering dropping the leading brand detergent, knowledge of consumer behavior or the but the pro forma became more complicated. assortment provided additional insights for The manufacturer of the leading brand deter- pricing decisions. gent gave the retailer off-invoice promotions One example was a price recommendation to keep their business; consequently, this allo- for a princess lightchaser (a glow product). The wed the retailer some options with product lightchaser was originally priced at $14, pricing. changed to $15, later to $10, and then raised r 2010 Macmillan Publishers Ltd. 1476-6930 Journal of Revenue and Pricing Management Vol. 9, 1/2, 4–22 19
  • 17. Quillinan Table 3: Covariates across industries Seasonality covariates (most/all industries) K Fourier Filter-based Covariates (multiple yearly cycles) K Other Data-derived Covariates (such as monthly contribution ratios) K Day-of-Week Covariates K Holiday/Special Event 0/1 Indicator Covariates K Other User-defined Covariates Customer-based covariates (Retail, hotel/cruise, distribution, services, casino, theme park, manufacturing) K Customer Demographics (total number of customers, Age/Financial Distribution, etc) K Customer Survey Information K Information on Prior Customer Relationships Competition based covariates (Airline, petroleum, financial services, apartment leasing, distribution, any industry with access to competitive data) K Market Strength Indices K Price or Volume of a Competitor’s key products K Your company’s Price Rank among competitors Financial covariates (primarily financial services, petroleum, manufacturing, transportation, communications, others where appropriate). K Gross Domestic Product (GDP) K Index of Leading Indicators K Gross National Happiness , a new concept relating happiness to economic growth K Population K Labor Force: Employment, Unemployment rate, Average Weekly earnings, Job security K Public Expenditure, Revenues, Budget Surplus and Deficit, National Debt K Personal Income, Expenditure, Savings K Broadband Internet Penetration K International: Balance of Payments (Current Account Balance of Trade) K Productivity Survey K Manufacturing output, Capacity Utilization, Inventories K Money supply, Interest Rates (Fed Funds, Prime, Major Competitors), Yield on various financial Instruments and Yield Curves. K Stock Market Indices (Dow-Jones Industrial Average, SP 500, etc) K Inflation, Consumer Price Index, Producer Price Index K New Home Sales K Retail Sales, Auto Sales K Lagging indicator, a historical indicator following an event that reacts slowly to economic changes K Genuine Progress Indicator, a concept in ecological economics and welfare economics that has been suggested as a replacement metric for GDP K Spot market prices K Energy prices, supply and consumption (Source: US Department of Energy, Energy Information Administration, http://eia.doe.gov) Climate covariates (retail, healthcare, pipeline, any industry where relevant) K Daily Temperature (Low, High, Average, #consecutive cooling/heating days) K Rainfall 20 r 2010 Macmillan Publishers Ltd. 1476-6930 Journal of Revenue and Pricing Management Vol. 9, 1/2, 4–22
  • 18. Introduction to normalization of demand data back to $15. Using the price-demand history, pricing analyst otherwise, and prevented poten- the system derived a price elasticity of tially disastrous price changes. In the end, the 0.0000175, and arrived at an ‘optimal’ price price-demand function from the normalization of $400 000. Needless to say, the pricing analyst process must pass the final diagnostic: the declined the price recommendation, even pricing analyst sanity check. though it had an expected revenue lift of $8.3 billion. Recent ‘flawed’ recommendations were ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS produced for ponchos. After increasing the The model and graphs presented in this article are based retail of ponchos by $1 – adults to $8 and youth on fictitious demand data. We did not use actual products to $7 – feedback from operations was received and demand data in the creation of the graphs. I thank the that guests were balking at the price increases, following individuals: Robert Shumsky for his encour- agement, and valuable feedback throughout the referee and purchasing a youth poncho instead. process; Utku Yildirim for his feedback on an early draft; Ponchos in general were up in revenue. The the Merchandise Revenue Management and Pricing systems generated pricing recommendations teams, in particular Ashley Bynoe and Tam Phan for for ponchos based on an elasticity of À2.6 for their valuable input, and Jacqueline Kappes for the pricing adults and a positive elasticity for youth. analyst examples; and to my wife Kim Quillinan and April Walsh for their review, suggestions and proofing. Although these elasticities supported opera- tional feedback, intervention by a pricing analyst was still needed to understand the poncho price change as a whole. Pricing REFERENCES Alley, W.M. (1987) A note on stagewise regression. The American decided to consolidate the price points and Statistician 41(2): 132–134. tried lowering the price of both poncho sizes; Bascle, G. (2008) Controlling for endogeneity with instrumental unfortunately, the price test results were not variables in strategic management research. Strategic Organiza- encouraging. After normalizing for attendance, tion 6(3): 285–327. Basmann, R., Molina, D. and Slottje, D. (1988) A note on weather, demographics and so on, there was no measuring Veblen’s theory of conspicuous consumption. increase in demand. This supports the pricing Review of Economics and Statistics 70(3): 531–535. analyst’s original hypothesis that ponchos are Becker, G.S. and Murphy, K.M. (1988) A rational theory of addiction. Journal of Political Economy 6(4): 675–700. inelastic and therefore price decreases do not Becker, G., Grossman, M. and Murphy, K. (1994) An empirical drive incremental revenue. analysis of cigarette addiction. American Economic Review 84: The third and final example was related to 396–418. Blattberg, R.C., Briesch, R. and Fox, E.J. (1995) How theme park novelty headwear, where a core promotions work. Marketing Science 14(3(2)): 122–132. product had been increased from $9.95 to Blattberg, R.C. and Wisniewski, K.J. (1989) Price-induced $11.95. At the same time, the novelty product patterns of competition. Marketing Science 8(4): 291–309. line was expanded and a create-your-own hat Chao, A. and Schor, J.B. (1998) Empirical tests of status consumption: Evidence from women’s cosmetics. Journal of was introduced. Both events led to cannibaliza- Economic Psychology 19(1): 107–131. tion of the core product’s demand. As a result, Dreze, X., Hoch, S.J. and Purk, M.E. (1994) Shelf management the price optimization system recommended and space elasticity. Journal of Retailing 70(4): 301–326. Erdem, T., Keane, M. and Sun, B. (2008) The impact of a price decrease, because the core product advertising on consumer price sensitivity in experience goods demand was down about 10 per cent. What the markets. Quantitative Marketing and Economics 6(2): 139–176. system failed to take into account was that the Espey, M. (1996) Explaining the variation in elasticity estimates of gasoline demand in the United States: A meta-analysis. Energy total hat business was up; consequently, no Journal 17(3): 49–60. decreases in retail prices of the core product are Fibich, G., Gavious, A. and Lowengard, O. (2005) The dynamics planned, as the quantity loss is believed stem to of price elasticity of demand in the presence of reference price from cannibalization and not the price increase. effects. Journal of the Academy of Marketing Science 33(1): 66–78. Fogarty, J. (2004) The Own-price Elasticity of Alcohol: A Meta- In conclusion, the human mind caught analysis. The University of Western Australia. Department of something about which the data told the Economics Working Paper, 04-01. r 2010 Macmillan Publishers Ltd. 1476-6930 Journal of Revenue and Pricing Management Vol. 9, 1/2, 4–22 21
  • 19. Quillinan Goel, R.K. and Morey, M.J. (1995) The interdependence of agement and Pricing Conference; 19 June, Montreal, cigarette and liquor demand. Southern Economic Journal 62(2): Quebec, Canada. 451–459. Schor, J.B. (1998) The Overspent American: Upscaling, Downshifting, Goodwin, P., Dargay, J. and Hanly, M. (2004) Elasticities of road and the New Consumer. New York: Basic Books. traffic and fuel consumption with respect to price and income: Schindler, R.M. (2006) The 99 price ending as a signal of a A review. Transport Reviews 24(3): 275–292. low-price appeal. Journal of Retailing 82(01): 71–77. Hays, C.L. (2004) What Wal-Mart knows about customers. The Thomas, M. and Morwitz, V.G. (2005) Penny wise and pound New York Times 14 November, http://www.nytimes.com/ foolish: The left digit effect in price cognition. Journal of 2004/11/14/business/yourmoney/14wal.html. Consumer Research 32(01): 54–64. Leibenstein, H. (1950) Bandwagon, Snob, and Veblen effects in Thompson, S.G. and Sharp, S.J. (1999) Explaining heterogeneity the theory of consumers’ demand. Quarterly Journal of in meta-analysis: A comparison of methods. Statistics in Economics 64(2): 183–207. Medicine 18: 2693–2708. Lyon, H. and Simon, J.L. (1968) Price elasticity of the demand Veblen, T. (1912) The Theory of the Leisure Class: An Economic for cigarettes in the United States. American Journal of Study of Institutions. New York: Macmillan. Agricultural Economics 50(4): 888–895. White, H. (1980) A heteroskedasticity-consistent covariance Quillinan, J.D. (2008) Normalization of demand data: An matrix estimator and a direct test for hetereoskedasticity. introduction to normalization. INFORMS Revenue Man- Econometrica 48(4): 817–838. 22 r 2010 Macmillan Publishers Ltd. 1476-6930 Journal of Revenue and Pricing Management Vol. 9, 1/2, 4–22